请输入您要查询的百科知识:

 

词条 Taylor rule
释义

  1. As an equation

  2. The Taylor principle

  3. Alternative versions of the rule

  4. Empirical relevance

  5. Criticisms

  6. See also

  7. References

  8. External links

{{Distinguish|Taylor Law|Taylor's law|Taylor's theorem}}

In economics, a Taylor rule is a reduced form approximation of the responsiveness of the nominal interest rate, as set by the central bank, to changes in inflation, output, or other economic conditions. In particular, the rule describes how, for each one-percent increase in inflation, the central bank tends to raise the nominal interest rate by more than one percentage point. This aspect of the rule is often called the Taylor principle. Although such rules may serve as concise, descriptive proxies for central bank policy, they are not explicitly prescriptively considered by central banks when setting nominal rates.

The rule was first proposed by John B. Taylor,[1] and simultaneously by Dale W. Henderson and Warwick McKibbin in 1993.[2]

It is intended to foster price stability by systematically reducing uncertainty and increasing the credibility of future actions by the central bank. It may also avoid the inefficiencies of time inconsistency from the exercise of discretionary policy.[3] The Taylor rule synthesized, and provided a compromise between, competing schools of economics thought in a language devoid of rhetorical passion.[4] Although many issues remain unresolved and views still differ about how the Taylor rule can best be applied in practice, research shows that the rule has advanced the practice of central banking.[5]

As an equation

According to Taylor's original version of the rule, the nominal interest rate should respond to

divergences of actual inflation rates from target inflation rates and of actual Gross Domestic Product (GDP) from potential GDP:

In this equation, is the target short-term nominal interest rate (e.g. the federal funds rate in the US, the Bank of England base rate in the UK), is the rate of inflation as measured by the GDP deflator, is the desired rate of inflation, is the assumed equilibrium real interest rate, is the logarithm of real GDP, and is the logarithm of potential output, as determined by a linear trend.

In this equation, both and should be positive (as a rough rule of thumb, Taylor's 1993 paper proposed setting ).[6] That is, the rule "recommends" a relatively high interest rate (a "tight" monetary policy) when inflation is above its target or when output is above its full-employment level, in order to reduce inflationary pressure. It recommends a relatively low interest rate ("easy" monetary policy) in the opposite situation, to stimulate output. Sometimes monetary policy goals may conflict, as in the case of stagflation, when inflation is above its target while output is below full employment. In such a situation, a Taylor rule specifies the relative weights given to reducing inflation versus increasing output.

The Taylor principle

By specifying , the Taylor rule says that an increase in inflation by one percentage point should prompt the central bank to raise the nominal interest rate by more than one percentage point (specifically, by , the sum of the two coefficients on in the equation above). Since the real interest rate is (approximately) the nominal interest rate minus inflation, stipulating implies that when inflation rises, the real interest rate should be increased. The idea that the real interest rate should be raised "more than one-for-one" to cool the economy when inflation increases (requiring the nominal interest rate to increase more than inflation does) has sometimes been called the Taylor principle.[7]

Alternative versions of the rule

While the Taylor principle has proved very influential, there is more debate about the other terms that should enter into the rule. According to some simple New Keynesian macroeconomic models, insofar as the central bank keeps inflation stable, the degree of fluctuation in output will be optimized (Blanchard and Gali call this property the 'divine coincidence'). In this case, the central bank does not need to take fluctuations in the output gap into account when setting interest rates (that is, it may optimally set .) On the other hand, other economists have proposed including additional terms in the Taylor rule to take into account financial conditions: for example, the interest rate might be raised when stock prices, housing prices, or interest rate spreads increase.

  • Taylor Rule 1993 - the original definition by John Taylor with
  • Taylor Rule 1999 - adapted and updated by John Taylor in a new research paper:

Empirical relevance

Although the Federal Reserve does not explicitly follow the Taylor rule, many analysts have argued that the rule provides a fairly accurate summary of US monetary policy under Paul Volcker and Alan Greenspan.[8][9] Similar observations have been made about central banks in other developed economies, both in countries like Canada and New Zealand that have officially adopted inflation targeting rules, and in others like Germany where the Bundesbank's policy did not officially target the inflation rate.[10][11] This observation has been cited by Clarida, Galí, and Gertler as a reason why inflation had remained under control and the economy had been relatively stable (the so-called 'Great Moderation') in most developed countries from the 1980s through the 2000s.[8] However, according to Taylor, the rule was not followed in part of the 2000s, possibly leading to the housing bubble.[12][13] Certain research has determined that some households form their expectations about the future path of interest rates, inflation, and unemployment in a way that is consistent with Taylor-type rules.[14]

Criticisms

Athanasios Orphanides (2003) claims that the Taylor rule can misguide policy makers since they face real-time data. He shows that the Taylor rule matches the US funds rate less perfectly when accounting for these informational limitations and that an activist policy following the Taylor rule would have resulted in an inferior macroeconomic performance during the Great Inflation of the seventies.[15]

In 2015, financial manager Bill Gross said the Taylor rule "must now be discarded into the trash bin of history", in light of tepid GDP growth in the years after 2009.[16] Gross believed low interest rates were not the cure for decreased growth, but the source of the problem.

See also

  • Monetary policy
  • McCallum rule
  • Monetary policy reaction function
  • Inflation targeting

References

1. ^{{cite paper |last=Taylor |first=John B. |year=1993 |title=Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice |work=Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy |volume=39 |url=http://www.stanford.edu/~johntayl/Papers/Discretion.PDF |pages=195–214 }} (The rule is introduced on page 202.)
2. ^{{cite paper |last=Henderson |first=D. W. |first2=W. |last2=McKibbin |year=1993 |title=A Comparison of Some Basic Monetary Policy Regimes for Open Economies: Implications of Different Degrees of Instrument Adjustment and Wage Persistence |journal=Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy |volume=39 |pages=221–318 |doi=10.1016/0167-2231(93)90011-K }}
3. ^Taylor, John (2012). First Principles: Five Keys to Restoring America's Economic Prosperity. New York: W.W. Norton & Company, Inc. p. 126
4. ^{{cite paper |work=Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Working Paper 07-11 |title=The Taylor Rule and the Transformation of Monetary Policy |year=2007 |last=Kahn |first=George A. |last2=Asso |first2=Pier Francesco |last3=Leeson |first3=Robert |ssrn=1088466 }}
5. ^{{cite paper |work=Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Working Paper 10-05 |last=Asso |first=Pier Francesco |last2=Kahn |first2=George A. |last3=Leeson |first3=Robert |title=The Taylor Rule and the Practice of Central Banking |year=2010 |ssrn=1553978 }}
6. ^Athanasios Orphanides (2008). "Taylor rules," The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. v. 8, pp. 2000-2004, equation (7).Abstract.
7. ^{{cite journal |title=Generalizing the Taylor Principle |first=Troy |last=Davig |first2=Eric M. |last2=Leeper |journal=American Economic Review |volume=97 |issue=3 |year=2007 |pages=607–635 |jstor=30035014 |doi=10.1257/aer.97.3.607}}
8. ^{{cite journal |last=Clarida |first=Richard |first2=Jordi |last2=Galí |first3=Mark |last3=Gertler |year=2000 |title=Monetary Policy Rules and Macroeconomic Stability: Theory and Some Evidence |journal=Quarterly Journal of Economics |volume=115 |issue=1 |pages=147–180 |doi=10.1162/003355300554692 |jstor=2586937 |citeseerx=10.1.1.111.7984 }}
9. ^{{Cite news |last=Lowenstein |first=Roger |title=The Education of Ben Bernanke | newspaper=The New York Times |date=2008-01-20 |url=https://www.nytimes.com/2008/01/20/magazine/20Ben-Bernanke-t.html}}
10. ^{{cite journal |last=Bernanke |first=Ben |first2=Ilian |last2=Mihov |year=1997 |title=What Does the Bundesbank Target? |journal=European Economic Review |volume=41 |issue=6 |pages=1025–1053 |doi=10.1016/S0014-2921(96)00056-6 }}
11. ^{{cite journal |last=Clarida |first=Richard |first2=Mark |last2=Gertler |first3=Jordi |last3=Galí |year=1998 |title=Monetary Policy Rules in Practice: Some International Evidence |journal=European Economic Review |volume=42 |issue=6 |pages=1033–1067 |doi=10.1016/S0014-2921(98)00016-6 }}
12. ^{{cite paper |url=http://www.stanford.edu/~johntayl/FCPR.pdf |title=The Financial Crisis and the Policy Responses: An Empirical Analysis of What Went Wrong |first=John B. |last=Taylor |year=2008 }}
13. ^{{cite book |last=Taylor |first=John B. |year=2009 |title=Getting Off Track: How Government Actions and Interventions Caused, Prolonged, and Worsened the Financial Crisis |location= |publisher=Hoover Institution Press |isbn=978-0-8179-4971-6 }}
14. ^{{cite paper |work=Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper 2012-01 |title=Do People Understand Monetary Policy? |first=Carlos |last=Carvalho |first2=Fernanda |last2=Nechio |year=2013 |ssrn=1984321 }}
15. ^{{cite journal |last=Orphanides |first=A. |year=2003 |title=The Quest for Prosperity without Inflation |journal=Journal of Monetary Economics |volume=50 |issue=3 |pages=633–663 |doi=10.1016/S0304-3932(03)00028-X |citeseerx=10.1.1.196.7048 }}
16. ^{{cite web |url=https://www.cnbc.com/2015/07/30/gross-low-rates-are-the-problem-not-the-solution.html |title=Gross: Low rates are the problem, not the solution |work=CNBC |author=Bill Gross |date=July 30, 2015 |accessdate=July 30, 2015}}

External links

  • Resources from John Taylor's web site.
  • Federal Reserve paper on the Taylor Rule.
{{Federal Reserve System}}{{Central banks}}{{DEFAULTSORT:Taylor Rule}}

2 : Federal Reserve System|Monetary policy

随便看

 

开放百科全书收录14589846条英语、德语、日语等多语种百科知识,基本涵盖了大多数领域的百科知识,是一部内容自由、开放的电子版国际百科全书。

 

Copyright © 2023 OENC.NET All Rights Reserved
京ICP备2021023879号 更新时间:2024/11/12 6:23:02