词条 | Wilhelm Röpke |
释义 |
| name = Wilhelm Röpke | school_tradition = Ordoliberalism | image = | image_size = | caption = | birth_date = {{birth date|mf=yes|1899|10|10}} | birth_place = Schwarmstedt, German Empire | death_date = {{Death date and age|mf=yes|1966|2|12|1899|10|10}} | death_place = Geneva, Switzerland | nationality = German | institution = University of Marburg, Istanbul University, Graduate Institute of International Studies | field = Economics, Ethics | alma_mater = University of Marburg | influences = Ludwig von Mises | influenced = Konrad Adenauer, Ludwig Erhard, Henry Hazlitt, F. A. Hayek | contributions = Theoretical foundation of the German economic miracle | awards = | signature = | repec_prefix = | repec_id = }}Wilhelm Röpke (October 10, 1899 – February 12, 1966) was Professor of Economics, first in Jena, then in Graz, Marburg, Istanbul, and finally Geneva, Switzerland, and one of the spiritual fathers of the social market economy, theorising and collaborating to organise the post-World War II economic re-awakening of the war-wrecked German economy, deploying a program sometimes referred to as the sociological neoliberalism (compared to ordoliberalism, a more sociologically inclined variant of German neoliberalism).[1] With Alfred Müller-Armack and Alexander Rüstow (sociological neoliberalism) and Walter Eucken and Franz Böhm (ordoliberalism) he elucidated the ideas, which then were introduced formally by Germany's post-World War II Minister for Economics Ludwig Erhard, operating under Konrad Adenauer's Chancellorship.[1] Röpke and his colleagues' economic influence therefore is considered largely responsible for enabling Germany's post-World War II "economic miracle". Röpke was also a historian and was nominated to the Nobel Prize in Literature in 1965.[2] {{liberalism sidebar}}LifeRöpke's opposition to the German Nazi regime led him (with his family) in 1933 to emigrate to Istanbul, Turkey, where he taught until 1937, before accepting a position at the Graduate Institute of International and Development Studies in Geneva, where he lived until his death, in 1966. WorkIn his youth, Röpke was first inspired by socialism and afterwards by the Austrian School economist Ludwig von Mises.[3] Despite this, the post-World War II economic liberation enabling Germany to once again lead Europe, which Röpke and his allies (Walter Eucken, Franz Böhm, Alfred Müller-Armack and Alexander Rüstow) were the intellectual muscle behind, occurred by implementing policy divergent to that advocated by Ludwig von Mises. Though the two men shared some beliefs in certain areas, Röpke & co. instead formed the school of ordoliberalism and advocated free trade but with more central bank and state influence than what Austrian School economists suggest is required.[4] Unlike many mainstream Austrian School economists, Röpke and the ordoliberalists conceded that the market economy can be more disruptive and inhumane unless intervention is permitted a role to play. (citation needed) Following Alexander Rüstow, Röpke concluded that free markets' vaunted efficiency and affluence can exact social and spiritual forfeits. In consequence, he envisioned a positive and more extensive role for the state, as rulemaker, enforcer of competition, and provider of basic social security.[3] During the Great Depression, Röpke argued in Crises and Cycles that a secondary deflation had to be combated through a fiscal reflation. It has been argued that the secondary deflation essentially is the same phenomenon that Taiwanese-American economist Richard C. Koo in later years has denoted as a balance sheet recession.[5] In spite of this, however, Röpke remained a political decentralist and rejected Keynesian economics, deriding it as "a typically intellectual construction that forgets the social reality behind the integral calculus".[3][6][7] For Röpke, rights and moral habits (Sitte) were key elements which the Central Bank and State (opposed to the Market-Economy) needed to subtly help organise. With a "conforming" social, economic, and financial policy, the task of which is to protect the weak "beyond the market," to equalize interests, set rules of the game, and limit market power, Röpke strove for an economic order of "economic humanism," something which he also referred to as the "Third Way." Röpke stood for a society and social policy in which human rights are given the highest importance. He believed that individualism must be balanced by a well-thought-out principle of sociality and humanity. Significantly, Röpke's economic thought is highly congruent with Catholic social teaching. As he grew older, Röpke increasingly appreciated the overall, general benefits of a society that embraces spirituality, particularly in contrast to societies where spirituality is marginalized or demonized.[3] InfluenceIn particular, from 1930 to 1931, Röpke served on a government commission examining unemployment and, from 1947 to 1948, he served on Germany's post-World War II currency reform council.[4] Furthermore, Röpke personally advised the Chancellor of (post-World War II) West Germany, Konrad Adenauer, and his Minister of Economics, Ludwig Erhard up until the late 1950s, and therefore is credited with contributing the intellectual backbone of the now famous German Economic "Miracle".[3] Occupying West Germany following the conclusion of World War II, the Western Allies (the US, Britain, and France) had continued to implement an economic policy of rationing as well as wage and price controls, coupled with the continued excessive printing of paper money. Production consequently collapsed and prominent businessmen once again became unwilling to accept the (relatively) worthless currency, triggering widespread shortages and the mainstreaming of a grey-market barter economy. Röpke's The Solution to the German Problem (1947) illuminated the negative implications of the Western Allies' continuing of Hitler's economic policies. Instead, Röpke proposed abolishing price controls and replacing the reichsmark with a sound, more trustworthy currency. Accordingly, price and wage controls were then incrementally abolished and on June 21, 1948, the new Deutsche Mark was introduced. These long-range policy initiatives, however, spawned some civil unrest immediately following their implementation because of a consequent increase in unemployment. Despite these disturbances and stoically supported by Röpke's learned newspaper writings, the Minister of Economics Ludwig Erhard persevered with foresight, and this eventually amounted to "a great personal vindication for Röpke": Röpke and his allies had "made West Germany immune to communism".[4] He was president of the Mont Pelerin Society from 1961 to 1962. But as a result of a long quarrel with Friedrich August von Hayek he stepped down and terminated his membership in it.[8] Works
See also
References1. ^1 Razeen Sally, Classical Liberalism and International Economic Order, Routledge, 2002, {{ISBN|0-415-16493-1}}, p. 106 2. ^https://www.nobelprize.org/nomination/literature/1965.html 3. ^1 2 3 4 [https://web.archive.org/web/20070323094516/http://www.findarticles.com/p/articles/mi_m0354/is_3_45/ai_n6140123 An essay about Röpke by John Attarian] 4. ^1 2 Samuel Gregg, Wilhelm Röpke's political economy, Edward Elgar Publishing Limited, 2010, {{ISBN|978-1-84844-222-1}}, p. 29 5. ^Olsen, Andreas Hardhaug. "Wilhelm Röpke and Richard C. Koo On Secondary Deflations and Balance Sheet Recessions." Economic Affairs 35.2 (2015): 215-224. 6. ^[https://mises.org/journals/rae/pdf/RAE10_1_6.PDF How Different Were Ropke and Mises?] Ivan Pongracic, Review of Ausrrian Economics 10, no. 1 (1997): 125–32 {{ISSN|0889-3047}} 7. ^[https://mises.org/store/Critics-of-Keynesian-Economics-P559.aspx See "The Economics Of Full Employment" in Critics of Keynesian Economics] 8. ^Philip Mirowski, Dieter Plehwe: The Road From Mont Pelerin. 2009, {{ISBN|978-0-674-03318-4}}, p. 19 Further reading
External links
14 : 1899 births|1966 deaths|People from Heidekreis|German anti-communists|German economists|Commanders Crosses of the Order of Merit of the Federal Republic of Germany|Emigrants from Nazi Germany|German expatriates in Turkey|German expatriates in Switzerland|20th-century scholars|German academics|German male non-fiction writers|Istanbul University faculty|Graduate Institute of International and Development Studies faculty |
随便看 |
|
开放百科全书收录14589846条英语、德语、日语等多语种百科知识,基本涵盖了大多数领域的百科知识,是一部内容自由、开放的电子版国际百科全书。