请输入您要查询的百科知识:

 

词条 Comparative advantage
释义

  1. Classical theory and David Ricardo's formulation

     Ricardo's example  Ricardian model   Terms of trade  

  2. Haberler's opportunity costs formulation

  3. Modern theories

     Dornbusch et al.'s continuum of goods formulation  Deardorff's general law of comparative advantage  Alternative approaches 

  4. Empirical approach to comparative advantage

     Direct test: natural experiment of Japan  Structural estimation  Earlier empirical work 

  5. Considerations

     Development economics 

  6. Criticism

      Unrealistic assumption 1: capital and labour are not internationally mobile    Unrealistic assumption 2: there are no externalities    Unrealistic assumption 3: productive resources move easily from one industry to another    Unrealistic assumption 4: the gains resulting from international trade are only static gains    Unrealistic assumption 5: trade will always be balanced and there is an adjustment mechanism    Unrealistic assumption 6: international trade is understood as bartering    Unrealistic assumption 7: labour or capital is used to its full potential  

  7. See also

  8. References

  9. Bibliography

  10. External links

The law or principle of comparative advantage holds that under free trade, an agent will produce more of and consume less of a good for which they have a comparative advantage.[1] Comparative advantage is the economic reality describing the work gains from trade for individuals, firms, or nations, which arise from differences in their factor endowments or technological progress.[2] In an economic model, agents have a comparative advantage over others in producing a particular good if they can produce that good at a lower relative opportunity cost or autarky price, i.e. at a lower relative marginal cost prior to trade.[3] One does not compare the monetary costs of production or even the resource costs (labor needed per unit of output) of production. Instead, one must compare the opportunity costs of producing goods across countries.[4]

David Ricardo developed the classical theory of comparative advantage in 1817 to explain why countries engage in international trade even when one country's workers are more efficient at producing every single good than workers in other countries. He demonstrated that if two countries capable of producing two commodities engage in the free market, then each country will increase its overall consumption by exporting the good for which it has a comparative advantage while importing the other good, provided that there exist differences in labor productivity between both countries.[5][6] Widely regarded as one of the most powerful[7] yet counter-intuitive[8] insights in economics, Ricardo's theory implies that comparative advantage rather than absolute advantage is responsible for much of international trade.

Classical theory and David Ricardo's formulation

Adam Smith first alluded to the concept of absolute advantage as the basis for international trade in The Wealth of Nations:

{{quote|text=If a foreign country can supply us with a commodity cheaper than we ourselves can make it, better buy it off them with some part of the produce of our own industry employed in a way in which we have some advantage. The general industry of the country, being always in proportion to the capital which employs it, will not thereby be diminished [...] but only left to find out the way in which it can be employed with the greatest advantage.[9]}}

Writing several decades after Smith in 1808, Robert Torrens articulated a preliminary definition of comparative advantage as the loss from the closing of trade:

{{quote|text=[I]f I wish to know the extent of the advantage, which arises to England, from her giving France a hundred pounds of broadcloth, in exchange for a hundred pounds of lace, I take the quantity of lace which she has acquired by this transaction, and compare it with the quantity which she might, at the same expense of labour and capital, have acquired by manufacturing it at home. The lace that remains, beyond what the labour and capital employed on the cloth, might have fabricated at home, is the amount of the advantage which England derives from the exchange.[10]}}

In 1817, David Ricardo published what has since become known as the theory of comparative advantage in his book On the Principles of Political Economy and Taxation.

Ricardo's example

In a famous example, Ricardo considers a world economy consisting of two countries, Portugal and England, which produce two goods of identical quality. In Portugal, the a priori more efficient country, it is possible to produce wine and cloth with less labor than it would take to produce the same quantities in England. However, the relative costs of producing those two goods differ between the countries.

Hours of work necessary to produce one unit
Country|ProduceClothWine
England100120
Portugal9080

In this illustration, England could commit 100 hours of labor to produce one unit of cloth, or produce {{sfrac|5|6}} units of wine. Meanwhile, in comparison, Portugal could commit 90 hours of labor to produce one unit of cloth, or produce {{sfrac|9|8}} units of wine. So, Portugal possesses an absolute advantage in producing cloth due to fewer labor hours, and England has a comparative advantage due to lower opportunity cost.

In the absence of trade, England requires 220 hours of work to both produce and consume one unit each of cloth and wine while Portugal requires 170 hours of work to produce and consume the same quantities. England is more efficient at producing cloth than wine, and Portugal is more efficient at producing wine than cloth. So, if each country specializes in the good for which it has a comparative advantage, then the global production of both goods increases, for England can spend 220 labor hours to produce 2.2 units of cloth while Portugal can spend 170 hours to produce 2.125 units of wine. Moreover, if both countries specialize in the above manner and England trades a unit of its cloth for {{sfrac|5|6}} to {{sfrac|9|8}} units of Portugal's wine, then both countries can consume at least a unit each of cloth and wine, with 0 to 0.2 units of cloth and 0 to 0.125 units of wine remaining in each respective country to be consumed or exported. Consequently, both England and Portugal can consume more wine and cloth under free trade than in autarky.

Ricardian model

The Ricardian model is a general equilibrium mathematical model of international trade. Although the idea of the Ricardian model was first presented in the Essay on Profits (a single-commodity version) and then in the Principles (a multi-commodity version) by David Ricardo, the first mathematical Ricardian model was published by William Whewell in 1833.[11] The earliest test of the Ricardian model was performed by G.D.A MacDougall, which was published in Economic Journal of 1951 and 1952.

[12] In the Ricardian model, trade patterns depend on productivity differences.

The following is a typical modern interpretation of the classical Ricardian model.[13] In the interest of simplicity, it uses notation and definitions, such as opportunity cost, unavailable to Ricardo.

The world economy consists of two countries, Home and Foreign, which produce wine and cloth. Labor, the only factor of production, is mobile domestically but not internationally; there may be migration between sectors but not between countries. We denote the labor force in Home by , the amount of labor required to produce one unit of wine in Home by , and the amount of labor required to produce one unit of cloth in Home by . The total amount of wine and cloth produced in Home are and respectively. We denote the same variables for Foreign by appending a prime. For instance, is the amount of labor needed to produce a unit of wine in Foreign.

We don't know if Home is more productive than Foreign in making cloth. That is, we don't know that . Similarly, we don't know if Home has an absolute advantage in wine. However, we will assume that Home is more relatively productive in cloth than Foreign:

Equivalently, we may assume that Home has a comparative advantage in cloth in the sense that it has a lower opportunity cost for cloth in terms of wine than Foreign:

In the absence of trade, the relative price of cloth and wine in each country is determined solely by the relative labor cost of the goods. Hence the relative autarky price of cloth is in Home and in Foreign. With free trade, the price of cloth or wine in either country is the world price or.

Instead of considering the world demand (or supply) for cloth and wine, we are interested in the world relative demand (or relative supply) for cloth and wine, which we define as the ratio of the world demand (or supply) for cloth to the world demand (or supply) for wine. In general equilibrium, the world relative price will be determined uniquely by the intersection of world relative demand and world relative supply curves.

We assume that the relative demand curve reflects substitution effects and is decreasing with respect to relative price. The behavior of the relative supply curve, however, warrants closer study. Recalling our original assumption that Home has a comparative advantage in cloth, we consider five possibilities for the relative quantity supplied at a given price.

  • If , then Foreign specializes in wine, for the wage in the wine sector is greater than the wage in the cloth sector. However, Home workers are indifferent between working in either sector. As a result, the quantity supplied can take any value.
  • If , then both Home and Foreign specialize in wine, for similar reasons as above, and so the quantity supplied is zero.
  • If , then Home specializes in cloth whereas Foreign specializes in wine. The quantity supplied is given by the ratio of the world production of cloth to the world production of wine.
  • If , then both Home and Foreign specialize in cloth. The quantity supplied tends to infinity as the quantity of wine supplied approaches zero.
  • If , then Home specializes in cloth while Foreign workers are indifferent between sectors. Again, the relative quantity supplied can take any value.

As long as the relative demand is finite, the relative price is always bounded by the inequality

In autarky, Home faces a production constraint of the form

from which it follows that Home's cloth consumption at the production possibilities frontier is

.

With free trade, Home produces cloth exclusively, an amount of which it exports in exchange for wine at the prevailing rate. Thus Home's overall consumption is now subject to the constraint

while its cloth consumption at the consumption possibilities frontier is given by

.

A symmetric argument holds for Foreign. Therefore, by trading and specializing in a good for which it has a comparative advantage, each country can expand its consumption possibilities. Consumers can choose from bundles of wine and cloth that they could not have produced themselves in closed economies.

Terms of trade

Terms of trade is the rate at which one good could be traded for another. If both countries specialize in the good for which they have a comparative advantage then trade, the terms of trade for a good (that benefit both entities) will fall between each entities opportunity costs. In the example above one unit of cloth would trade for between units of wine and units of wine.[14]

Haberler's opportunity costs formulation

In 1930 Gottfried Haberler detached the doctrine of comparative advantage from Ricardo’s labor theory of value and provided a modern opportunity-cost formulation. Haberler’s reformulation of comparative advantage revolutionized the theory of international trade and laid the conceptual groundwork of modern trade theories.

Haberler’s innovation was to reformulate the theory of comparative advantage such that the value of good X is measured in terms of the forgone units of production of good Y rather than the labor units necessary to produce good X, as in the Ricardian formulation. Haberler implemented this opportunity-cost formulation of comparative advantage by introducing the concept of a production possibility curve into international trade theory.[15]

Modern theories

Since 1817, economists have attempted to generalize the Ricardian model and derive the principle of comparative advantage in broader settings, most notably in the neoclassical specific factors Ricardo-Viner and factor proportions Heckscher–Ohlin models. Subsequent developments in the new trade theory, motivated in part by the empirical shortcomings of the H–O model and its inability to explain intra-industry trade, have provided an explanation for aspects of trade that are not accounted for by comparative advantage.[16] Nonetheless, economists like Alan Deardorff,[17] Avinash Dixit, Gottfried Haberler, and Victor D. Norman[18] have responded with weaker generalizations of the principle of comparative advantage, in which countries will only tend to export goods for which they have a comparative advantage.

Dornbusch et al.'s continuum of goods formulation

In both the Ricardian and H–O models, the comparative advantage theory is formulated for a 2 countries/2 commodities case. It can be extended to a 2 countries/many commodities case, or a many countries/2 commodities case. Adding commodities in order to have a smooth continuum of goods is the major insight of the seminal paper by Dornbusch, Fisher, and Samuelson. In fact, inserting an increasing number of goods into the chain of comparative advantage makes the gaps between the ratios of the labor requirements negligible, in which case the three types of equilibria around any good in the original model collapse to the same outcome. It notably allows for transportation costs to be incorporated, although the framework remains restricted to two countries.[19][20] But in the case with many countries (more than 3 countries) and many commodities (more than 3 commodities), the notion of comparative advantage requires a substantially more complex formulation.[21]

Deardorff's general law of comparative advantage

Skeptics of comparative advantage have underlined that its theoretical implications hardly hold when applied to individual commodities or pairs of commodities in a world of multiple commodities. Deardorff argues that the insights of comparative advantage remain valid if the theory is restated in terms of averages across all commodities. His models provide multiple insights on the correlations between vectors of trade and vectors with relative-autarky-price measures of comparative advantage. What has become to be known as the "Deardorff's general law of comparative advantage" is a model incorporating multiple goods, and which takes into account tariffs, transportation costs, and other obstacles to trade.

Alternative approaches

Recently, Y. Shiozawa succeeded in constructing a theory of international value in the tradition of Ricardo's cost-of-production theory of value.[22] This was based on a wide range of assumptions: Many countries; Many commodities; Several production techniques for a product in a country; Input trade (intermediate goods are freely traded); Durable capital goods with constant efficiency during a predetermined lifetime; No transportation cost (extendable to positive cost cases).

In a famous comment McKenzie pointed that "A moment's consideration will convince one that Lancashire would be unlikely to produce cotton cloth if the cotton had to be grown in England."[23] However, McKenzie and later researchers could not produce a general theory which includes traded input goods because of the mathematical difficulty.[24] As John Chipman points it, McKenzie found that "introduction of trade in intermediate product necessitates a fundamental alteration in classical analysis."[25] Durable capital goods such as machines and installations are inputs to the productions in the same title as part and ingredients.

In view of the new theory, no physical criterion exists.[26] The competitive patterns are determined by the traders trials to find cheapest products in a world. The search of cheapest product is achieved by world optimal procurement. Thus the new theory explains how the global supply chains are formed.[27]

Empirical approach to comparative advantage

Comparative advantage is a theory about the benefits that specialization and trade would bring, rather than a strict prediction about actual behavior. (In practice, governments restrict international trade for a variety of reasons; under Ulysses S. Grant, the US postponed opening up to free trade until its industries were up to strength, following the example set earlier by Britain.[28]) Nonetheless there is a large amount of empirical work testing the predictions of comparative advantage. The empirical works usually involve testing predictions of a particular model. For example, the Ricardian model predicts that technological differences in countries result in differences in labor productivity. The differences in labor productivity in turn determine the comparative advantages across different countries. Testing the Ricardian model for instance involves looking at the relationship between relative labor productivity and international trade patterns. A country that is relatively efficient in producing shoes tends to export shoes.

Direct test: natural experiment of Japan

Assessing the validity of comparative advantage on a global scale with the examples of contemporary economies is analytically challenging because of the multiple factors driving globalization: indeed, investment, migration, and technological change play a role in addition to trade. Even if we could isolate the workings of open trade from other processes, establishing its causal impact also remains complicated: it would require a comparison with a counterfactual world without open trade. Considering the durability of different aspects of globalization, it is hard to assess the sole impact of open trade on a particular economy.

Daniel Bernhofen and John Brown have attempted to address this issue, by using a natural experiment of a sudden transition to open trade in a market economy. They focus on the case of Japan.[29][30]. The Japanese economy indeed developed over several centuries under autarky and a quasi-isolation from international trade but was, by the mid-19th century, a sophisticated market economy with a population of 30 million. Under Western military pressure, Japan opened its economy to foreign trade through a series of unequal treaties.

In 1859, the treaties limited tariffs to 5% and opened trade to Westerners. Considering that the transition from autarky, or self-sufficiency, to open trade was brutal, few changes to the fundamentals of the economy occurred in the first 20 years of trade. The general law of comparative advantage theorizes that an economy should, on average, export goods with low self-sufficiency prices and import goods with high self-sufficiency prices. Bernhofen and Brown found that by 1869, the price of Japan's main export, silk and derivatives, saw a 100% increase in real terms, while the prices of numerous imported goods declined of 30-75%. In the next decade, the ratio of imports to gross domestic product reached 4%.[31]

Structural estimation

Another important way of demonstrating the validity of comparative advantage has consisted in 'structural estimation' approaches. These approaches have built on the Ricardian formulation of two goods for two countries and subsequent models with many goods or many countries. The aim has been to reach a formulation accounting for both multiple goods and multiple countries, in order to reflect real-world conditions more accurately. Jonathan Eaton and Samuel Kortum underlined that a convincing model needed to incorporate the idea of a 'continuum of goods' developed by Dornbusch et al. for both goods and countries. They were able to do so by allowing for an arbitrary (integer) number i of countries, and dealing exclusively with unit labor requirements for each good (one for each point on the unit interval) in each country (of which there are i).[32]

Earlier empirical work

Two of the first tests of comparative advantage were by MacDougall (1951, 1952).[33][34] A prediction of a two-country Ricardian comparative advantage model is that countries will export goods where output per worker (i.e. productivity) is higher. That is, we expect a positive relationship between output per worker and number of exports. MacDougall tested this relationship with data from the US and UK, and did indeed find a positive relationship. The statistical test of this positive relationship was replicated[35][36] with new data by Stern (1962) and Balassa (1963).

Dosi et al. (1988)[37] conduct a book-length empirical examination that suggests that international trade in manufactured goods is largely driven by differences in national technological competencies.

One critique of the textbook model of comparative advantage is that there are only two goods. The results of the model are robust to this assumption. Dornbusch et al. (1977)[38] generalized the theory to allow for such a large number of goods as to form a smooth continuum. Based in part on these generalizations of the model, Davis (1995)[39] provides a more recent view of the Ricardian approach to explain trade between countries with similar resources.

More recently, Golub and Hsieh (2000)[40] presents modern statistical analysis of the relationship between relative productivity and trade patterns, which finds reasonably strong correlations, and Nunn (2007)[41] finds that countries that have greater enforcement of contracts specialize in goods that require relationship-specific investments.

Taking a broader perspective, there has been work about the benefits of international trade. Zimring & Etkes (2014)[42] finds that the Blockade of the Gaza Strip, which substantially restricted the availability of imports to Gaza, saw labor productivity fall by 20% in three years. Markusen et al. (1994)[43] reports the effects of moving away from autarky to free trade during the Meiji Restoration, with the result that national income increased by up to 65% in 15 years.

{{clear}}

Considerations

Development economics

The theory of comparative advantage, and the corollary that nations should specialize, is criticized on pragmatic grounds within the import substitution industrialization theory of development economics, on empirical grounds by the Singer–Prebisch thesis which states that terms of trade between primary producers and manufactured goods deteriorate over time, and on theoretical grounds of infant industry and Keynesian economics. In older economic terms, comparative advantage has been opposed by mercantilism and economic nationalism. These argue instead that while a country may initially be comparatively disadvantaged in a given industry (such as Japanese cars in the 1950s), countries should shelter and invest in industries until they become globally competitive. Further, they argue that comparative advantage, as stated, is a static theory – it does not account for the possibility of advantage changing through investment or economic development, and thus does not provide guidance for long-term economic development.

Much has been written since Ricardo as commerce has evolved and cross-border trade has become more complicated. Today trade policy tends to focus more on "competitive advantage" as opposed to "comparative advantage". One of the most in-depth research undertakings on "competitive advantage" was conducted in the 1980s as part of the Reagan administration's Project Socrates to establish the foundation for a technology-based competitive strategy development system that could be used for guiding international trade policy.

Criticism

Several arguments have been advanced against using comparative advantage as a justification for advocating free trade, and they have gained an audience among economists. For example, James Brander and Barbara Spencer demonstrated how, in a strategic setting where a few firms compete for the world market, export subsidies and import restrictions can keep foreign firms from competing with national firms, increasing welfare in the country implementing these so-called strategic trade policies.[44]

However, the overwhelming consensus of the economics profession remains that while these arguments are theoretically valid under certain assumptions, these assumptions do not usually hold and should not be used to guide trade policy.[45] Gregory Mankiw, chairman of the Harvard Economics Department, has said: ″Few propositions command as much consensus among professional economists as that open world trade increases economic growth and raises living standards.″[46]

Economist James K. Galbraith disputes these claims of the benefit of comparative advantage. He states that "free trade has attained the status of a god" and that "{{nbsp}}... none of the world's most successful trading regions, including Japan, Korea, Taiwan, and now mainland China, reached their current status by adopting neoliberal trading rules." He argues that "{{nbsp}}... comparative advantage is based upon the concept of constant returns: the idea that you can double or triple the output of any good simply by doubling or tripling the inputs. But this is not generally the case. For manufactured products, increasing returns, learning, and technical change are the rule, not the exception; the cost of production falls with experience. With increasing returns, the lowest cost will be incurred by the country that starts earliest and moves fastest on any particular line. Potential competitors have to protect their own industries if they wish them to survive long enough to achieve competitive scale."[47]

Galbraith then explains that nations trapped into specializing in agriculture are condemned to perpetual poverty. Agriculture is dependent on a finite natural resource called land. People can't make more of it. As the population increases the per capita land resources decreases. Also the average farm size has also been increasing. If a nation is not allowed to expand into manufacturing and only specialize in agriculture, that nation is condemned to an ever expanding poverty. Galbraith summarizes: "Comparative advantage has very little practical use for trade strategy. Diversification, not specialization, is the main path out of underdevelopment, and effective diversification requires a strategic approach to trade policy. It cannot mean walling off the outside world, but it is also a goal not easily pursued under a dogmatic commitment to free trade."[48]

According to historian Cecil Woodham-Smith, Ireland in the 1800s is an example of the dangers of specialization. When the union with Great Britain was formed in 1800, Irish textile industries protected by tariffs were exposed to world markets where England had a comparative advantage in technology, experience and scale of operation which devastated the Irish industry. Ireland was forced to specialize in the export of grain while the displaced Irish labor was forced into subsistence farming and relying on the potato for survival. When the potato blight occurred the resulting famine killed at least one million Irish in one of the worst famines in European history. As Woodham-Smith would later comment, "the Irish peasant was told to replace the potato by eating his grain, but Trevelyan once again refused to take any steps to curb the export of food from Ireland. 'Do not encourage the idea of prohibiting exports,' he wrote, on September 3, (1846) 'perfect free trade is the right course'."[49]

The classical and neoclassical formulations of comparative advantage theory differ in the tools they use but share the same basis and logic. Comparative advantage theory says that market forces lead all factors of production to their best use in the economy. It indicates that international free trade would be beneficial for all participating countries as well as for the world as a whole because they could increase their overall production and consume more by specializing according to their comparative advantages. Goods would become cheaper and available in larger quantities. Moreover, this specialization would not be the result of chance or political intent, but would be automatic. However, the theories of free trade and comparative advantage are based on assumptions that are neither theoretically nor empirically valid[50]:

Unrealistic assumption 1: capital and labour are not internationally mobile

The international immobility of labour and capital is essential to the theory of comparative advantage. Without this, there would be no reason for international free trade to be regulated by comparative advantages. Classical and neoclassical economists all assume that labour and capital do not circulate between nations. At the international level, only the goods produced can move freely, with capital and labour trapped in countries. David Ricardo was aware that the international immobility of labour and capital is an indispensable hypothesis. He devoted half of his explanation of the theory to it in his book. He even explained that if labour and capital could move internationally, then comparative advantages could not determine international trade. Ricardo assumed that the reasons for the immobility of the capital would be:[50]

{{quote|text=[T]he fancied or real insecurity of capital, when not under the immediate control of its owner, together with the natural disinclination which every man has to quit the country of his birth and connexions, and intrust himself with all his habits fixed, to a strange government and new laws.}}

Neoclassical economists, for their part, argue that the scale of these movements of workers and capital is negligible. They developed the theory of price compensation by factor that makes these movements superfluous.

In practice, however, workers move in large numbers from one country to another. Today, labour migration is truly a global phenomenon. And, with the reduction in transport and communication costs, capital has become increasingly mobile and frequently moves from one country to another. Moreover, the neoclassical assumption that factors are trapped at the national level has no theoretical basis and the assumption of factor price equalisation cannot justify international immobility. Moreover, there is no evidence that factor prices are equal worldwide. Comparative advantages cannot therefore determine the structure of international trade[50].

If they are internationally mobile and the most productive use of factors is in another country, then free trade will lead them to migrate to that country. This will benefit the nation to which they emigrate, but not necessarily the others.

Unrealistic assumption 2: there are no externalities

An externality is the term used when the price of a product does not reflect its cost or real economic value. The classic negative externality is environmental degradation, which reduces the value of natural resources without increasing the price of the product that has caused them harm. The classic positive externality is technological encroachment, where one company's invention of a product allows others to copy or build on it, generating wealth that the original company cannot capture. If prices are wrong due to positive or negative externalities, free trade will produce sub-optimal results[50].

For example, goods from a country with lax pollution standards will be too cheap. As a result, its trading partners will import too much. And the exporting country will export too much, concentrating its economy too much in industries that are not as profitable as they seem, ignoring the damage caused by pollution.

On the positive externalities, if an industry generates technological spinoffs for the rest of the economy, then free trade can let that industry be destroyed by foreign competition because the economy ignores its hidden value. Some industries generate new technologies, allow improvements in other industries and stimulate technological advances throughout the economy; losing these industries means losing all industries that would have resulted in the future[50].

Unrealistic assumption 3: productive resources move easily from one industry to another

Comparative advantage theory deals with the best use of resources and how to put the economy to its best use. But this implies that the resources used to manufacture one product can be used to produce another object. If they cannot, imports will not push the economy into industries better suited to its comparative advantage and will only destroy existing industries[50].

For example, when workers cannot move from one industry to another - usually because they do not have the right skills or do not live in the right place - changes in the economy's comparative advantage will not shift them to a more appropriate industry, but rather to unemployment or precarious and unproductive jobs[50].

Unrealistic assumption 4: the gains resulting from international trade are only static gains

Comparative advantage theory allows for a "static" and not a "dynamic" analysis of the economy. That is, it examines the facts at a single point in time and determines the best response to those facts at that point in time, given our productivity in various industries. But when it comes to long-term growth, it says nothing about how the facts can change tomorrow and how they can be changed in someone's favour. It does not indicate how best to transform factors of production into more productive factors in the future[50].

According to theory, the only advantage of international trade is that goods become cheaper and available in larger quantities. Improving the static efficiency of existing resources would therefore be the only advantage of international trade. And the neoclassical formulation assumes that the factors of production are given only exogenously. Exogenous changes can come from population growth, industrial policies, the rate of capital accumulation (propensity for security) and technological inventions, among others. Dynamic developments endogenous to trade such as economic growth are not integrated into Ricardo's theory. And this is not affected by what is called "dynamic comparative advantage". In these models, comparative advantages develop and change over time, but this change is not the result of trade itself, but of a change in exogenous factors[50].

However, the world, and in particular the industrialized countries, are characterized by dynamic gains endogenous to trade, such as technological growth that has led to an increase in the standard of living and wealth of the industrialized world. In addition, dynamic gains are more important than static gains.

Unrealistic assumption 5: trade will always be balanced and there is an adjustment mechanism

A crucial assumption in both the classical and neoclassical formulation of comparative advantage theory is that trade is balanced, which means that the value of imports is equal to the value of each country's exports. The volume of trade may change, but international trade will always be balanced at least after a certain adjustment period. The balance of trade is essential for theory because the resulting adjustment mechanism is responsible for transforming the comparative advantages of production costs into absolute price advantages. And this is necessary because it is the absolute price differences that determine the international flow of goods. Since consumers buy a good from the one who sells it cheapest, comparative advantages in terms of production costs must be transformed into absolute price advantages. In the case of floating exchange rates, it is the exchange rate adjustment mechanism that is responsible for this transformation of comparative advantages into absolute price advantages. In the case of fixed exchange rates, neoclassical theory suggests that trade is balanced by changes in wage rates[50].

So if trade were not balanced in itself and if there were no adjustment mechanism, there would be no reason to achieve a comparative advantage. However, trade imbalances are the norm and balanced trade is in practice only an exception. In addition, financial crises such as the Asian crisis of the 1990s show that balance of payments imbalances are rarely benign and do not self-regulate. There is no adjustment mechanism in practice. Comparative advantages do not turn into price differences and therefore cannot explain international trade flows[50].

Thus, theory can very easily recommend a trade policy that gives us the highest possible standard of living in the short term but none in the long term. This is what happens when a nation runs a trade deficit, which necessarily means that it goes into debt with foreigners or sells its existing assets to them. Thus, the nation applies a frenzy of consumption in the short term followed by a long-term decline.

Unrealistic assumption 6: international trade is understood as bartering

The assumption that trade will always be balanced is a corollary of the fact that trade is understood as barter. The definition of international trade as barter trade is the basis for the assumption of balanced trade. Ricardo insists that international trade takes place as if it were purely a barter trade, a presumption that is maintained by subsequent classical and neoclassical economists. The quantity of money theory, which Ricardo uses, assumes that money is neutral and neglects the velocity of a currency. Money has only one function in international trade, namely as a means of exchange to facilitate trade[50].

In practice, however, the velocity of circulation is not constant and the quantity of money is not neutral for the real economy. A capitalist world is not characterized by a barter economy but by a market economy. The main difference in the context of international trade is that sales and purchases no longer necessarily have to coincide. The seller is not necessarily obliged to buy immediately. Thus, money is not only a means of exchange. It is above all a means of payment and is also used to store value, settle debts and transfer wealth. Thus, unlike the barter hypothesis of the comparative advantage theory, money is not a commodity like any other. Rather, it is of practical importance to specifically own money rather than any commodity. And money as a store of value in a world of uncertainty has a significant influence on the motives and decisions of wealth holders and producers[50].

Unrealistic assumption 7: labour or capital is used to its full potential

Ricardo and later classical economists assume that labour tends towards full employment and that capital is always fully used in a liberalized economy, because no capital owner will leave its capital unused but will always seek to make a profit from it. That there is no limit to the use of capital is a consequence of Jean-Baptiste Say's law, which presumes that production is limited only by resources and is also adopted by neoclassical economists[50].

From a theoretical point of view, comparative advantage theory must assume that labour or capital is used to its full potential and that resources limit production. There are two reasons for this: the realization of gains through international trade and the adjustment mechanism. In addition, this assumption is necessary for the concept of opportunity costs. If unemployment (or underutilized resources) exists, there are no opportunity costs, because the production of one good can be increased without reducing the production of another good. Since comparative advantages are determined by opportunity costs in the neoclassical formulation, these cannot be calculated and this formulation would lose its logical basis[50].

If a country's resources were not fully utilized, production and consumption could be increased at the national level without participating in international trade. The whole raison d'être of international trade would disappear, as would the possible gains. In this case, a State could even earn more by refraining from participating in international trade and stimulating domestic production, as this would allow it to employ more labour and capital and increase national income. Moreover, any adjustment mechanism underlying the theory no longer works if unemployment exists[50].

In practice, however, the world is characterised by unemployment. Unemployment and underemployment of capital and labour are not short-term phenomena, but are common and widespread. Unemployment and untapped resources are more the rule than the exception.

See also

{{Portal|Business and economics}}
  • Bureau of Labor Statistics
  • Keynesian beauty contest
  • Resource curse
  • Revealed comparative advantage

References

1. ^{{cite book|last1=Dixit|first1=Avinash|last2=Norman|first2=Victor|title=Theory of International Trade: A Dual, General Equilibrium Approach|year=1980|publisher=Cambridge University Press|location=Cambridge|page=2}}
2. ^{{cite book|last1=Maneschi|first1=Andrea|title=Comparative Advantage in International Trade: A Historical Perspective|year=1998|publisher=Elgar|location=Cheltenham|page=1}}
3. ^{{cite web|url=http://www.bls.gov/bls/glossary.htm|title=BLS Information |date=February 28, 2008|work=Glossary|publisher=U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics Division of Information Services |accessdate=2009-05-05}}
4. ^{{cite web|title=The Theory of Comparative Advantage: Overview|url=http://catalog.flatworldknowledge.com/bookhub/reader/28?e=fwk-61960-chab#fwk-61960-ch02_s02|website=Flat World Knowledge|accessdate=23 February 2015}}
5. ^Baumol, William J. and Alan S. Binder, 'Economics: Principles and Policy', [https://books.google.com/books?id=6Kedl8ZTTe0C&lpg=PA49&dq=%22law%20of%20comparative%20advantage%22&pg=PA50#v=onepage&q=%22law%20of%20comparative%20advantage%22&f p. 50]
6. ^{{cite book |last1=O'Sullivan |first1=Arthur |authorlink1=Arthur O'Sullivan (economist) |last2=Sheffrin |first2=Steven M. |title=Economics: Principles in Action |edition=2nd |series=The Wall Street Journal: Classroom Edition |year=2003 |origyear= January 2002|publisher= Pearson Prentice Hall: Addison Wesley Longman|location=Upper Saddle River, New Jersey |isbn=978-0-13-063085-8 |page= 444 }}
7. ^{{cite web|url=http://internationalecon.com/Trade/Tch40/T40-0.php |title=International Trade Theory and Policy|author=Steven M Suranovic|year=2010}}
8. ^{{cite web|url=http://web.mit.edu/krugman/www/ricardo.htm | author=Krugman, Paul|title=Ricardo's Difficult Idea |year=1996 |accessdate=2014-08-09}}
9. ^{{cite book|last1=Smith|first1=Adam|title=An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations|date=1776}}
10. ^{{cite book|last1=Torrens|first1=Lionel|title=The Economists Refuted and Other Early Economic Writings|year=1808|publisher=Kelley|location=New York|edition=1984|page=37}}
11. ^{{cite book |title= David Ricardo: Critical Assessments|last= Wood |first= John Cunningham|year= 1991 |publisher= Taylor & Francis |location= |isbn= 9780415063807|page= 312 |url= https://books.google.com/?id=h5GzUUfTL4sC&pg=PA312&dq=Ricardian+model#v=onepage&q=Ricardian%20model&f=false}}
12. ^{{cite book |title= International Economics: A European Focus|last= Ingham |first= Barbara|year= 2004 |publisher= Pearson Education |location= |isbn= 9780273655077|page= 22 |url= https://books.google.com/?id=zIaS9R7HUGIC&printsec=frontcover&dq=international+economics#v=onepage&q=RIcardian%20model&f=false}}
13. ^{{cite book|last1=Krugman|first1=Paul|last2=Obstfeld|first2=Maurice|title=International Economics: Theory and Policy|year=1988|publisher=Prentice Hall|location=New York|pages=27–36|edition=2008}}
14. ^{{Cite web|url=http://www.reviewecon.com/comparative-advantage.html|title=AP Economics Review: Comparative Advantage, Absolute Advantage, and Terms of Trade|last=|first=|date=2016-09-28|website=www.reviewecon.com/comparative-advantage.html|publisher=|access-date=}}
15. ^{{cite journal|last1=Bernhofen|first1=Daniel|title=Gottfried haberler's 1930 reformulation of comparative advantage in retrospect|journal=Review of International Economics|date=2005|volume=13|issue=5|pages=997–1000|doi=10.1111/j.1467-9396.2005.00550.x}}
16. ^{{cite book|last1=Maneschi|first1=Andrea|title=Comparative Advantage in International Trade: A Historical Perspective|year=1998|publisher=Elgar|location=Cheltenham|pages=6–13}}
17. ^{{cite journal|last1=Deardorff|first1=Alan|title=The General Validity of the Law of Comparative Advantage|journal=Journal of Political Economy|date=Oct 1980|volume=88|issue=5|pages=941–57|doi=10.1086/260915}}
18. ^{{cite book|last1=Dixit|first1=Avinash|last2=Norman|first2=Victor|title=Theory of International Trade: A Dual, General Equilibrium Approach|year=1980|publisher=Cambridge University Press|location=Cambridge|pages=93–126}}
19. ^{{Cite journal | last1 = Dornbusch | first1 = R. | last2 = Fischer | first2 = S. | last3 = Samuelson | first3 = P. A. | year = 1977 | title = Comparative Advantage, Trade, and Payments in a Ricardian Model with a Continuum of Goods | journal = American Economic Review | volume = 67 | issue = 5 | pages = 823–39 | publisher = | jstor = 1828066 | url = | format = | accessdate = }}
20. ^{{Cite journal | doi = 10.2307/1885496| jstor = 1885496| title = Heckscher-Ohlin Trade Theory with a Continuum of Goods| journal = The Quarterly Journal of Economics| volume = 95| issue = 2| pages = 203–224| date = 1980| last1 = Dornbusch | first1 = R. | last2 = Fischer | first2 = S. | last3 = Samuelson | first3 = P. A. }}
21. ^{{Cite journal | doi = 10.1111/j.1467-9396.2005.00552.x| title = How Robust is Comparative Advantage?| journal = Review of International Economics| volume = 13| issue = 5| pages = 1004–16| date = 2005| last1 = Deardorff | first1 = A. V.| url = https://deepblue.lib.umich.edu/bitstream/2027.42/73670/1/j.1467-9396.2005.00552.x.pdf}}
22. ^Y. Shiozawa, A new construction of Ricardian trade theory / A many-country, many commodity case with intermediates goods and choice of production techniques, Evolutionary and Institutional Economics Review 3(2): 141–87, 2007. Y. Shiozawa, A Final Solution of the Ricardo Problem on International Values, Iwanami Shoten, 2014.
23. ^L. W. McKenzie Specialization and Efficiency in World Production, Review of Economic Studies 21(3): 165–80. Citation from p.179.
24. ^For the brief history of the theory of intermediates goods, see Appendix A: Previous Literature in A. Deardorff, Ricardian Comparative Advantage with Intermediate Inputs, The North American Journal of Economics and Finance 16(1): 11–34, March 2005. http://fordschool.umich.edu/rsie/workingpapers/Papers501-525/r501.pdf
25. ^Chipman, John S. (1965). "A Survey of the Theory of International Trade: Part 1, The Classical Theory". Econometrica 33 (3): 477–519. Section 1.8, p. 509.
26. ^Deardorff examines 10 versions of definitions in two groups but could not give a general formula for the case with intermdiate goods. A. Deardorff, Ricardian Comparative Advantage with Intermediate Inputs, The North American Journal of Economics and Finance 16(1): 11–34, March 2005. See also http://fordschool.umich.edu/rsie/workingpapers/Papers501-525/r501.pdf See Appendix A: Previous Literature in particular.
27. ^Y. Shiozawa (2016) The revival of classical theory of values, in Nobuharu Yokokawa et als. (Eds.) The Rejuvenation of Political Economy, May 2016, Oxon and New York: Routledge. Chapter 8, pp. 151–72. Y. Shiozawa, The New Interpretation of Ricardo's Four Magic Numbers and the New Theory of International Values / A Comment on Faccarello's "Comparative advantage"). A paper read on a conference on March 23, 2016.
28. ^{{Cite journal|last=Chang|first=Ha-Joon|author-link=Ha-Joon Chang|date=December 2003|title=Kicking Away the Ladder: The "Real" History of Free Trade|url=|journal=FPIF Special Report|volume=|pages=|via=}}
29. ^{{cite journal|last1=Bernhofen|first1=Daniel|last2=Brown|first2=John|title=A Direct Test of the Theory of Comparative Advantage: The Case of Japan|journal=Journal of Political Economy|date=2004|volume=112|issue=1|pages=48–67|doi=10.1086/379944}}
30. ^{{cite journal|last1=Bernhofen|first1=Daniel|last2=Brown|first2=John|title=An Empirical Assessment of the Comparative Advantage Gains from Trade: Evidence from Japan|journal=American Economic Review|date=2005|volume=95|issue=1|pages=208–225|doi=10.1257/0002828053828491}}
31. ^{{cite journal|last1=Bernhofen|first1=Daniel|last2=John|first2=Brown|title=Testing the General Validity of the Heckscher-Ohlin Theorem|journal=American Economic Journal: Microeconomics|date=2016|volume=8|issue=4|pages=54–90|doi=10.1257/mic.20130126}}
32. ^{{cite journal|last1=Eaton|first1=Jonathan|last2=Kortum|first2=Samuel|title=Putting Ricardo to Work†|journal=Journal of Economic Perspectives|date=Spring 2012|volume=26|issue=2|pages=65–90|doi=10.1257/jep.26.2.65}}
33. ^{{cite news | author=MacDougall, G. D. A.| title=British and American exports: A study suggested by the theory of comparative costs. Part I.| journal=The Economic Journal| year=1951| volume=61 | issue=244|pages=697–724}}
34. ^{{cite news | author=MacDougall, G. D. A.| title=British and American exports: A study suggested by the theory of comparative costs. Part II.| journal=The Economic Journal| year=1952| volume=62 | issue=247|pages=487–521}}
35. ^{{cite news | author=Stern, Robert M.| title=British and American productivity and comparative costs in international trade| journal=Oxford Economic Papers |year=1962| pages=275–96.}}
36. ^{{cite news | author=Balassa, Bela. | title=An empirical demonstration of classical comparative cost theory| journal=The Review of Economics and Statistics|year=1963 |pages=231–238.}}
37. ^{{cite book | author=Dosi, G., Pavitt, K, & L. Soete | title=The Economics of Technical Change and International Trade | year=1988 | publisher=Brighton: Wheatsheaf }}
38. ^{{cite news |author1=Dornbusch, R. |author2=Fischer, S. |author3=P. Samuelson |last-author-amp=yes | title=Comparative Advantage, Trade and Payments in a Ricardian Model with a Continuum of Goods | journal=American Economic Review | volume=67 | year=1977 | pages=823–39 }}
39. ^{{cite news | author=Davis, D. | title=Intraindustry Trade: A Heckscher-Ohlin-Ricardo Approach | journal=Journal of International Economics | volume=39 | year=1995 | pages=201–26 | doi=10.1016/0022-1996(95)01383-3}}
40. ^{{cite news |author1=Golub, S. |author2=C-T Hsieh | title=Classical Ricardian Theory of Comparative Advantage Revisited | journal=Review of International Economics | volume=8 | issue=2 | year=2000 | pages=221–34 }}
41. ^{{cite news | author=Nunn, N| title=Relationship-Specificity, Incomplete Contracts, and the Pattern of Trade| journal=Quarterly Journal of Economics | volume=122 | issue=2 | year=2007 |pages=569–600}}
42. ^Zimring, A. & Etkes, H. (2014) "When Trade Stops: Lessons from the 2007–2010 Gaza Blockade". Journal of International Economics, forthcoming.
43. ^{{cite book|author1=Markusen, J.R. |author2=Melvin J.R., Kaempfer |author3=W.M., K. Maskus |last-author-amp=yes | year=1994| title=International Trade: Theory and Evidence | url= http://www.colorado.edu/Economics/courses/Markusen/textbook/mmkm3.pdf |accessdate=2014-08-13 | page=218| publisher=McGraw-Hill | isbn=978-0070404472 }}
44. ^{{cite news |last=Krugman |first=Paul R. |title=Is Free Trade Passe? |journal=Journal of Economic Perspectives |year=1987 |volume=1 |issue=2 |pages=131–44}}
45. ^{{cite news |last=Irwin |first=Douglas. |title=Retrospectives: Challenges to Free Trade |journal=Journal of Economic Perspectives |year=1991 |volume=5 |issue=2 |pages=201–08}}
46. ^{{cite web|url=http://gregmankiw.blogspot.com/2006/05/outsourcing-redux.html| author=Mankiw, N.G. |title=Outsourcing Redux|website= Greg Mankiw's Blog: Random Observations for Students of Economics|date=May 7, 2006}}
47. ^James K. Galbraith, The Predator State, Free Press, 2008, pp. 68–69
48. ^{{Cite book|url=|title=The Predator State: How conservatives abandoned the free market and why liberals should too|last=K.,|first=Galbraith, James|publisher=|year=2008|isbn=9781416566830|edition=First Free Press hardcover|location=New York|pages=70|oclc=192109752|author-link=James K. Galbraith}}
49. ^Cecil Woodham-Smith, Ireland 1845–1849, 1962, pp. 49, 100, 118
50. ^10 11 12 13 14 15 {{Cite thesis|last=Maurin|first=Max|title=Les fondements non neoclassiques du protectionnisme|date=2013|degree=Thèse de doctorat|publisher=Université Montesquieu-Bordeaux IV|url=http://www.sudoc.abes.fr/xslt/DB=2.1/SET=3/TTL=1//CLK?IKT=1016&TRM=Les+fondements+non+neoclassiques+du+protectionnisme&COOKIE=U10178,Klecteurweb,I250,B341720009+,SY,NLECTEUR+WEBOPC,D2.1,E0cd3c1ea-4,A,H,R208.80.153.50,FY|place=1995-2013, France}}

Bibliography

{{refbegin|30em}}
  • {{cite journal | last1 = Bernhofen | first1 = Daniel M | year = 2005 | title = Gottfried haberler's 1930 reformulation of comparative advantage in retrospect | url = | journal = Review of International Economics | volume = 13 | issue = 5| pages = 997–1000 | doi=10.1111/j.1467-9396.2005.00550.x}}
  • {{cite journal | last1 = Bernhofen | first1 = Daniel M. | last2 = Brown | first2 = John C. | year = 2004 | title = A Direct Test of the Theory of Comparative Advantage: The Case of Japan | url = | journal = Journal of Political Economy | volume = 112 | issue = 1| pages = 48–67 | doi=10.1086/379944| citeseerx = 10.1.1.194.9649 }}
  • {{cite journal | last1 = Bernhofen | first1 = Daniel M. | last2 = Brown | first2 = John C. | year = 2005 | title = An Empirical Assessment of the Comparative Advantage Gains from Trade: Evidence from Japan | url = | journal = American Economic Review | volume = 95 | issue = 1| pages = 208–25 | doi=10.1257/0002828053828491}}
  • {{cite journal | last1 = Bernhofen | first1 = Daniel M. | last2 = Brown | first2 = John C. | year = 2016 | title = Testing the General Validity of the Heckscher-Ohlin Theorem | url = | journal = American Economic Journal: Microeconomics | volume = 8 | issue = 4| pages = 54–90 | doi=10.1257/mic.20130126}}
  • {{cite journal | last1 = Findlay | first1 = Ronald | year = 1987 | title = Comparative Advantage | url = | journal = The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics | volume = 1 | issue = | pages = 514–17 }}
  • Markusen, Melvin, Kaempfer and Maskus, "International Trade: Theory and Evidence"
  • Hardwick, Khan and Langmead (1990). An Introduction to Modern Economics 3rd ed.
  • A. O'Sullivan & S.M. Sheffrin (2003). Economics. Principles & Tools.
{{refend}}

External links

  • "Cloth for Wine? The Relevance of Ricardo’s Comparative Advantage in the 21st Century" VoxEU Ebook.
  • David Ricardo's The Principles of Trade and Taxation (original source text)
  • Ricardo's Difficult Idea, Paul Krugman's 1996 exploration of why non-economists don't understand the idea of comparative advantage
  • The Ricardian Model of Comparative Advantage
  • What is comparative advantage? | Investopedia
  • Comparative Advantage Definition | Investopedia
  • Comparative Advantage Calculator
{{Trade|state=expanded}}{{DEFAULTSORT:Comparative Advantage}}

4 : Microeconomic theories|Classical economics|International trade theory|Economics comparisons

随便看

 

开放百科全书收录14589846条英语、德语、日语等多语种百科知识,基本涵盖了大多数领域的百科知识,是一部内容自由、开放的电子版国际百科全书。

 

Copyright © 2023 OENC.NET All Rights Reserved
京ICP备2021023879号 更新时间:2024/11/13 23:54:02