请输入您要查询的百科知识:

 

词条 Emissions trading
释义

  1. Overview

  2. History

  3. Market and least-cost

      Emission markets    Pollution markets  

  4. Public opinion

  5. Comparison with other methods of emission reduction

      Baseline and credit   Pollution tax  Command-and-control regulation 

  6. Economics of international emissions trading

     Example  Applying the economic theory   Prices versus quantities, and the safety valve   Carbon leakage  Trade 

  7. Trading systems

     Kyoto Protocol  Australia  New Zealand  European Union  Tokyo, Japan  United States  Sulfur dioxide  Nitrogen oxides  Volatile organic compounds  Greenhouse gases (federal)  State and regional programs  South Korea  China   Pollution Permit Trading    Carbon Market   India  Renewable energy certificates 

  8. Carbon market

     Market trend  Business reaction 

  9. Measuring, reporting, verification

  10. Enforcement

  11. Criticism

     Offsets  Permit supply level  Permit allocation versus auctioning  Distributional effects 

  12. Linking

  13. See also

  14. References

  15. Further reading

  16. External links

{{Green economics sidebar}}Emissions trading (also known as cap and trade) is a market-based approach to controlling pollution by providing economic incentives for achieving reductions in the emissions of pollutants.[1]

A central authority (usually a governmental body) allocates or sells a limited number of permits to discharge specific quantities of a specific pollutant per time period.[2] Polluters are required to hold permits in amount equal to their emissions. Polluters that want to increase their emissions must buy permits from others willing to sell them.[1][2][3][4][5] Financial derivatives of permits can also be traded on secondary markets.[8]

Various countries, states and groups of companies have adopted such trading systems, notably for mitigating climate change.[6]

In contrast to command-and-control environmental regulations such as best available technology (BAT) standards and government subsidies, cap and trade (CAT) programs are a type of flexible environmental regulation[7] that allows organizations to decide how best to meet policy targets.

There are active trading programs in several air pollutants. For greenhouse gases, which cause climate change, permit units are often called carbon credits. The largest greenhouse gases (GHG) trading program is the European Union Emission Trading Scheme,[8] which trades primarily in European Union Allowances (EUAs); the Californian scheme trades in California Carbon Allowances, the New Zealand scheme in New Zealand Units and the Australian scheme in Australian Units.[7][9] The United States has a national market to reduce acid rain and several regional markets in nitrogen oxides.[10] Recent reduction in California's GHG emissions are not attributed to carbon trading but to other factors such as renewable portfolio standards and energy efficiency policies; the 'cap' in California has been and continues to be larger than actual emission rates.[11] GHG emissions increased at more than half of industrial point sources regulated by California's cap and trade program from 2013 to 2015.[12]

In theory, polluters who can reduce emissions most cheaply will do so, achieving the emission reduction at the lowest cost to society.[13] Cap and trade is meant to provide the private sector with the flexibility required to reduce emissions while stimulating technological innovation and economic growth.[14] In practice the theory can fall short. Environmental hotspots arise and impact areas nearest pollution sources when credits are purchased in lieu of emission reductions; low-income neighborhoods and people of color tend to be located near large industrial point sources and suffer adverse health and welfare effects disproportionately.[15] In addition to environmental justice issues, historically cap and trade policy is not as effective as performance standards for reducing air pollutant emissions. For example, sulfur dioxide (SO2) emissions and acidic sulfate deposition decreased to a larger extent more rapidly in Europe than in the United States over similar time periods with Europe employing traditional control approaches compared to the U.S.' subsidized market approach.[16]

Overview

Pollution is a prime example of a market externality. An externality is an effect of some activity on an entity (such as a person) that is not party to a market transaction related to that activity. Emissions trading is a market-based approach to address pollution. The overall goal of an emissions trading plan is to minimize the cost of meeting a set emissions target.[17]

In an emissions trading system, the government sets an overall limit on emissions, and defines permits (also called allowances), or limited authorizations to emit, up to the level of the overall limit. The government may sell the permits, but in many existing schemes, it gives permits to participants (regulated polluters) equal to each participant's baseline emissions. The baseline is determined by reference to the participant's historical emissions. To demonstrate compliance, a participant must hold permits at least equal to the quantity of pollution it actually emitted during the time period. If every participant complies, the total pollution emitted will be at most equal to the sum of individual limits.[18] Because permits can be bought and sold, a participant can choose either to use its permits exactly (by reducing its own emissions); or to emit less than its permits, and perhaps sell the excess permits; or to emit more than its permits, and buy permits from other participants. In effect, the buyer pays a charge for polluting, while the seller gains a reward for having reduced emissions.

In many schemes, organizations which do not pollute (and therefore have no obligations) may also trade permits and financial derivatives of permits. In some schemes, participants can bank allowances to use in future periods.[19] In some schemes, a proportion of all traded permits must be retired periodically, causing a net reduction in emissions over time. Thus, environmental groups may buy and retire permits, driving up the price of the remaining permits according to the law of demand.[20] In most schemes, permit owners can donate permits to a nonprofit entity and receive a tax deduction. Usually, the government lowers the overall limit over time, with an aim towards a national emissions reduction target.[17]

According to the Environmental Defense Fund, cap-and-trade is the most environmentally and economically sensible approach to controlling greenhouse gas emissions, the primary cause of global warming, because it sets a limit on emissions, and the trading encourages companies to innovate in order to emit less.[21]

"International trade can offer a range of positive and negative incentives to promote international cooperation on climate change (robust evidence, medium agreement). Three issues are key to developing constructive relationships between international trade and climate agreements: how existing trade policies and rules can be modified to be more climate friendly; whether border adjustment measures (BAMs) or other trade measures can be effective in meeting the goals of international climate agreements; whether the UNFCCC, World Trade Organization (WTO), hybrid of the two, or a new institution is the best forum for a trade-and-climate architecture."[22]

History

The international community began the long process towards building effective international and domestic measures to tackle GHG emissions (carbon dioxide, methane, nitrous oxide, hydroflurocarbons, perfluorocarbons, sulphur hexafluoride) in response to the increasing assertions that global warming is happening due to man-made emissions and the uncertainty over its likely consequences. That process began in Rio in 1992, when 160 countries agreed the UN Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC). The UNFCCC is, as its title suggests, simply a framework; the necessary detail was left to be settled by the Conference of Parties (CoP) to the UNFCCC.[18]

The efficiency of what later was to be called the "cap-and-trade" approach to air pollution abatement was first demonstrated in a series of micro-economic computer simulation studies between 1967 and 1970 for the National Air Pollution Control Administration (predecessor to the United States Environmental Protection Agency's Office of Air and Radiation) by Ellison Burton and William Sanjour. These studies used mathematical models of several cities and their emission sources in order to compare the cost and effectiveness of various control strategies.[23][24][25][26][27] Each abatement strategy was compared with the "least-cost solution" produced by a computer optimization program to identify the least-costly combination of source reductions in order to achieve a given abatement goal. In each case it was found that the least-cost solution was dramatically less costly than the same amount of pollution reduction produced by any conventional abatement strategy.[28] Burton and later Sanjour along with Edward H. Pechan continued improving [29] and advancing[30] these computer models at the newly created U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. The agency introduced the concept of computer modeling with least-cost abatement strategies (i.e., emissions trading) in its 1972 annual report to Congress on the cost of clean air.[31] This led to the concept of "cap and trade" as a means of achieving the "least-cost solution" for a given level of abatement.

The development of emissions trading over the course of its history can be divided into four phases:[32]

  1. Gestation: Theoretical articulation of the instrument (by Coase,&91;33&93; Crocker,&91;34&93; Dales,&91;35&93; Montgomery&91;13&93; etc.) and, independent of the former, tinkering with "flexible regulation" at the US Environmental Protection Agency.
  2. Proof of Principle: First developments towards trading of emission certificates based on the "offset-mechanism" taken up in Clean Air Act in 1977. A company could get allowance from the Act on a greater amount of emission when it paid another company to reduce the same pollutant.&91;36&93;
  3. Prototype: Launching of a first "cap-and-trade" system as part of the US Acid Rain Program in Title IV of the 1990 Clean Air Act, officially announced as a paradigm shift in environmental policy, as prepared by "Project 88", a network-building effort to bring together environmental and industrial interests in the US.
  4. Regime formation: branching out from the US clean air policy to global climate policy, and from there to the European Union, along with the expectation of an emerging global carbon market and the formation of the "carbon industry".

In the United States, the acid rain related emission trading system was principally conceived by C. Boyden Gray, a G.H.W. Bush administration attorney. Gray worked with the Environmental Defense Fund (EDF), who worked with the EPA to write the bill that became law as part of the Clean Air Act of 1990. The new emissions cap on NOx and {{SO2|link=yes}} gases took effect in 1995, and according to Smithsonian magazine, those acid rain emissions dropped 3 million tons that year.[37] In 1997, the CoP agreed, in what has been described as a watershed in international environmental treaty making, the Kyoto Protocol where 38 developed countries (Annex 1 countries) committed themselves to targets and timetables for the reduction of GHGs.[38] These targets for developed countries are often referred to as Assigned Amounts.

The resulting inflexible limitations on GHG growth could entail very large costs, perhaps running into many trillions of dollars globally countries, if have to solely rely on their own domestic measures is one important economic reality recognised by many of the countries that signed the Kyoto Protocol.[39] As a result, international mechanisms which would allow developed countries flexibility to meet their targets were included in the Kyoto Protocol. The purpose of these mechanisms is to allow the parties to find the most economical ways to achieve their targets. These international mechanisms are outlined under Kyoto Protocol.[18]

On April 17, 2009, the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) formally announced that it had found that greenhouse gas (GHG) poses a threat to public health and the environment (EPA 2009a). This announcement was significant because it gives the executive branch the authority to impose carbon regulations on carbon-emitting entities.[40]

A carbon cap-and-trade system is to be introduced nationwide in China in 2016[41] (China's National Development and Reform Commission proposed that an absolute cap be placed on emission by 2016.)[42]

Market and least-cost

{{Quotebox
| quote = Economy-wide pricing of carbon is the centre piece of any policy designed to reduce emissions at the lowest possible costs.
| source = Ross Garnaut, lead author of the Garnaut Climate Change Review [43]
| width = 12em
| align = right
}}

Some economists have urged the use of market-based instruments such as emissions trading to address environmental problems instead of prescriptive "command-and-control" regulation.[44] Command and control regulation is criticized for being insensitive to geographical and technological differences, and therefore inefficient.;[45] however, this is not always so, as shown by the WW-II rationing program in the U.S. in which local and regional boards made adjustments for these differences.[46]

After an emissions limit has been set by a government political process, individual companies are free to choose how or whether to reduce their emissions. Failure to report emissions and surrender emission permits is often punishable by a further government regulatory mechanism, such as a fine that increases costs of production. Firms will choose the least-cost way to comply with the pollution regulation, which will lead to reductions where the least expensive solutions exist, while allowing emissions that are more expensive to reduce.

Under an emissions trading system, each regulated polluter has flexibility to use the most cost-effective combination of buying or selling emission permits, reducing its emissions by installing cleaner technology, or reducing its emissions by reducing production. The most cost-effective strategy depends on the polluter's marginal abatement cost and the market price of permits. In theory, a polluter's decisions should lead to an economically efficient allocation of reductions among polluters, and lower compliance costs for individual firms and for the economy overall, compared to command-and-control mechanisms.[47][18]

Emission markets

For emissions trading where greenhouse gases are regulated, one emissions permit is considered equivalent to one metric ton of carbon dioxide (CO2) emissions. Other names for emissions permits are carbon credits, Kyoto units, assigned amount units, and Certified Emission Reduction units (CER). These permits can be sold privately or in the international market at the prevailing market price. These trade and settle internationally, and hence allow permits to be transferred between countries. Each international transfer is validated by the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC). Each transfer of ownership within the European Union is additionally validated by the European Commission.

Emissions trading programmes such as the European Union Emissions Trading System (EU ETS) complement the country-to-country trading stipulated in the Kyoto Protocol by allowing private trading of permits. Under such programmes – which are generally co-ordinated with the national emissions targets provided within the framework of the Kyoto Protocol – a national or international authority allocates permits to individual companies based on established criteria, with a view to meeting national and/or regional Kyoto targets at the lowest overall economic cost.[48]

Trading exchanges have been established to provide a spot market in permits, as well as futures and options market to help discover a market price and maintain liquidity. Carbon prices are normally quoted in euros per tonne of carbon dioxide or its equivalent (CO2e). Other greenhouse gases can also be traded, but are quoted as standard multiples of carbon dioxide with respect to their global warming potential. These features reduce the quota's financial impact on business, while ensuring that the quotas are met at a national and international level.

Currently, there are six exchanges trading in UNFCCC related carbon credits: the Chicago Climate Exchange (until 2010[49]), European Climate Exchange, NASDAQ OMX Commodities Europe, PowerNext, Commodity Exchange Bratislava and the European Energy Exchange. NASDAQ OMX Commodities Europe listed a contract to trade offsets generated by a CDM carbon project called Certified Emission Reductions. Many companies now engage in emissions abatement, offsetting, and sequestration programs to generate credits that can be sold on one of the exchanges. At least one private electronic market has been established in 2008: CantorCO2e.[50] Carbon credits at Commodity Exchange Bratislava are traded at special platform called Carbon place.[51]

Trading in emission permits is one of the fastest-growing segments in financial services in the City of London with a market estimated to be worth about €30 billion in 2007. Louis Redshaw, head of environmental markets at Barclays Capital, predicts that "carbon will be the world's biggest commodity market, and it could become the world's biggest market overall."[52]

Pollution markets

An emission license directly confers a right to emit pollutants up to a certain rate.

In contrast, a pollution license for a given location confers the right to emit pollutants at a rate which will cause no more than a specified increase at the pollution-level. For concreteness, consider the following model.[13]

  • There are agents each of which emits pollutants.
  • There are locations each of which suffers pollution .
  • The pollution is a linear combination of the emissions. The relation between and is given by a diffusion matrix , such that: .

As an example, consider three countries along a river (as in the fair river sharing setting).

  • Pollution in the upstream country is determined only by the emission of the upstream country: .
  • Pollution in the middle country is determined by its own emission and by the emission of country 1: .
  • Pollution in the downstream country is the sum of all emissions: .

So the matrix in this case is a triangular matrix of ones.

Each pollution-license for location permits its holder to emit pollutants that will cause at most this level of pollution at location . Therefore, a polluter that affects water quality at a number of points has to hold a portfolio of licenses covering all relevant monitoring-points. In the above example, if country 2 wants to emit a unit of pollutant, it should purchase two permits: one for location 2 and one for location 3.

Montgomery shows that, while both markets lead to efficient license allocation, the market in pollution-licenses is more widely applicable than the market in emission-licenses.[13]

Public opinion

In the United States, most polling shows large support for emissions trading (often referred to as cap-and-trade). This majority support can be seen in polls conducted by Washington Post/ABC News,[53] Zogby International[54] and Yale University.[55] A new Washington Post-ABC poll reveals that majorities of the American people believe in climate change, are concerned about it, are willing to change their lifestyles and pay more to address it, and want the federal government to regulate greenhouse gases. They are, however, ambivalent on cap-and-trade.[56]

More than three-quarters of respondents, 77.0%, reported they “strongly support” (51.0%) or “somewhat support” (26.0%) the EPA's decision to regulate carbon emissions. While 68.6% of respondents reported being “very willing” (23.0%) or “somewhat willing” (45.6%), another 26.8% reported being “somewhat unwilling” (8.8%) or “not at all willing” (18.0%) to pay higher prices for “Green” energy sources to support funding for programs that reduce the effect of global warming.[56]

According to PolitiFact, it is a misconception that emissions trading is unpopular in the United States because of earlier polls from Zogby International and Rasmussen which misleadingly include "new taxes" in the questions (taxes aren't part of emissions trading) or high energy cost estimates.[57]

Comparison with other methods of emission reduction

Cap and trade is the textbook exaple of an emissions trading program. Other market-based approaches include baseline-and-credit, and pollution tax. They all put a price on pollution (for example, see carbon price), and so provide an economic incentive to reduce pollution beginning with the lowest-cost opportunities. By contrast, in a command-and-control approach, a central authority designates pollution levels each facility is allowed to emit. Cap and trade essentially functions as a tax where the tax rate is variable based on the relative cost of abatement per unit, and the tax base is variable based on the amount of abatement needed.{{citation needed|date=April 2018}}

Baseline and credit

In a baseline and credit program, polluters can create permits, called credits or offsets, by reducing their emissions below a baseline level, which is often the historical emissions level from a designated past year.[58] Such credits can be bought by polluters that have a regulatory limit.[59]

Pollution tax

Emissions fees or environmental tax is a surcharge on the pollution created while producing goods and services.[60] For example, a carbon tax is a tax on the carbon content of fossil fuels that aims to discourage their use and thereby reduce carbon dioxide emissions.[58] The two approaches are overlapping sets of policy designs. Both can have a range of scopes, points of regulation, and price schedules. They can be fair or unfair, depending on how the revenue is used. Both have the effect of increasing the price of goods (such as fossil fuels) to consumers.[61] A comprehensive, upstream, auctioned cap-and-trade system is very similar to a comprehensive, upstream carbon tax. Yet, many commentators sharply contrast the two approaches.

The main difference is what is defined and what derived. A tax is a price control, while cap-and-trade method acts is a quantity control instrument.[61] That is, a tax is a unit price for pollution that is set by authorities, and the market determines the quantity emitted; in cap and trade, authorities determine the amount of pollution, and the market determines the price.[62] This difference affects a number of criteria.[60]

Responsiveness to inflation: Cap-and-trade has the advantage that it adjusts to inflation (changes to overall prices) automatically, while emissions fees must be changed by regulators.

Responsiveness to cost changes: It is not clear which approach is better. It is possible to combine the two into a safety valve price: a price set by regulators, at which polluters can buy additional permits beyond the cap.

Responsiveness to recessions: This point is closely related to responsiveness to cost changes, because recessions cause a drop in demand. Under cap and trade, the emissions cost automatically decreases, so a cap-and-trade scheme adds another automatic stabilizer to the economy - in effect, an automatic fiscal stimulus. However, a lower pollution price also results in reduced efforts to reduce pollution. If the government is able to stimulate the economy regardless of the cap-and-trade scheme, an excessively low price causes a missed opportunity to cut emissions faster than planned. Instead, it might be better to have a price floor (a tax). This is especially true when cutting pollution is urgent, as with greenhouse gas emissions. A price floor also provides certainty and stability for investment in emissions reductions: recent experience from the UK shows that nuclear power operators are reluctant to invest on "un-subsidised" terms unless there is a guaranteed price floor for carbon (which the EU emissions trading scheme does not presently provide).

Responsiveness to uncertainty: As with cost changes, in a world of uncertainty, it is not clear whether emissions fees or cap-and-trade systems are more efficient—it depends on how fast the marginal social benefits of reducing pollution fall with the amount of cleanup (e.g., whether inelastic or elastic marginal social benefit schedule).

Other: The magnitude of the tax will depend on how sensitive the supply of emissions is to the price. The permit price of cap-and-trade will depend on the pollutant market. A tax generates government revenue, but full-auctioned emissions permits can do the same. A similar upstream cap-and-trade system could be implemented. An upstream carbon tax might be the simplest to administer. Setting up a complex cap-and-trade arrangement that is comprehensive has high institutional needs.[63]

Command-and-control regulation

Command and control is a system of regulation that prescribes emission limits and compliance methods for each facility or source. It is the traditional approach to reducing air pollution.[58]

Command-and-control regulations are more rigid than incentive-based approaches such as pollution fees and cap and trade. An example of this is a performance standard which sets an emissions goal for each polluter that is fixed and, therefore, the burden of reducing pollution cannot be shifted to the firms that can achieve it more cheaply. As a result, performance standards are likely to be more costly overall.[60] The additional costs would be passed to end consumers.[64]

Economics of international emissions trading

{{trade bloc}}

It is possible for a country to reduce emissions using a Command-Control approach, such as regulation, direct and indirect taxes. The cost of that approach differs between countries because the Marginal Abatement Cost Curve (MAC) — the cost of eliminating an additional unit of pollution — differs by country. It might cost China $2 to eliminate a ton of CO2, but it would probably cost Norway or the U.S. much more. International emissions-trading markets were created precisely to exploit differing MACs.

Example

Emissions trading through Gains from Trade can be more beneficial for both the buyer and the seller than a simple emissions capping scheme.

Consider two European countries, such as Germany and Sweden. Each can either reduce all the required amount of emissions by itself or it can choose to buy or sell in the market.

Suppose Germany can abate its CO2 at a much cheaper cost than Sweden, i.e. MACS > MACG where the MAC curve of Sweden is steeper (higher slope) than that of Germany, and RReq is the total amount of emissions that need to be reduced by a country.

On the left side of the graph is the MAC curve for Germany. RReq is the amount of required reductions for Germany, but at RReq the MACG curve has not intersected the market emissions permit price of CO2 (market permit price = P = λ). Thus, given the market price of CO2 allowances, Germany has potential to profit if it abates more emissions than required.

On the right side is the MAC curve for Sweden. RReq is the amount of required reductions for Sweden, but the MACS curve already intersects the market price of CO2 permits before RReq has been reached. Thus, given the market price of CO2 permits, Sweden has potential to make a cost saving if it abates fewer emissions than required internally, and instead abates them elsewhere.

In this example, Sweden would abate emissions until its MACS intersects with P (at R*), but this would only reduce a fraction of Sweden's total required abatement.

After that it could buy emissions credits from Germany for the price P (per unit). The internal cost of Sweden's own abatement, combined with the permits it buys in the market from Germany, adds up to the total required reductions (RReq) for Sweden. Thus Sweden can make a saving from buying permits in the market (Δ d-e-f). This represents the "Gains from Trade", the amount of additional expense that Sweden would otherwise have to spend if it abated all of its required emissions by itself without trading.

Germany made a profit on its additional emissions abatement, above what was required: it met the regulations by abating all of the emissions that was required of it (RReq). Additionally, Germany sold its surplus permits to Sweden, and was paid P for every unit it abated, while spending less than P. Its total revenue is the area of the graph (RReq 1 2 R*), its total abatement cost is area (RReq 3 2 R*), and so its net benefit from selling emission permits is the area (Δ 1-2-3) i.e. Gains from Trade

The two R* (on both graphs) represent the efficient allocations that arise from trading.

  • Germany: sold (R - RReq) emission permits to Sweden at a unit price P.
  • Sweden bought emission permits from Germany at a unit price P.

If the total cost for reducing a particular amount of emissions in the Command Control scenario is called X, then to reduce the same amount of combined pollution in Sweden and Germany, the total abatement cost would be less in the Emissions Trading scenario i.e. (X — Δ 123 - Δ def).

The example above applies not just at the national level, but also between two companies in different countries, or between two subsidiaries within the same company.

Applying the economic theory

The nature of the pollutant plays a very important role when policy-makers decide which framework should be used to control pollution. CO2 acts globally, thus its impact on the environment is generally similar wherever in the globe it is released. So the location of the originator of the emissions does not matter from an environmental standpoint.[65]

The policy framework should be different for regional pollutants[66] (e.g. SO2 and NOx, and also mercury) because the impact of these pollutants may differ by location. The same amount of a regional pollutant can exert a very high impact in some locations and a low impact in other locations, so it matters where the pollutant is released. This is known as the Hot Spot problem.

A Lagrange framework is commonly used to determine the least cost of achieving an objective, in this case the total reduction in emissions required in a year. In some cases, it is possible to use the Lagrange optimization framework to determine the required reductions for each country (based on their MAC) so that the total cost of reduction is minimized. In such a scenario, the Lagrange multiplier represents the market allowance price (P) of a pollutant, such as the current market price of emission permits in Europe and the USA.[67]

Countries face the permit market price that exists in the market that day, so they are able to make individual decisions that would minimize their costs while at the same time achieving regulatory compliance. This is also another version of the Equi-Marginal Principle, commonly used in economics to choose the most economically efficient decision.

Prices versus quantities, and the safety valve

There has been longstanding debate on the relative merits of price versus quantity instruments to achieve emission reductions.[68]

An emission cap and permit trading system is a quantity instrument because it fixes the overall emission level (quantity) and allows the price to vary. Uncertainty in future supply and demand conditions (market volatility) coupled with a fixed number of pollution permits creates an uncertainty in the future price of pollution permits, and the industry must accordingly bear the cost of adapting to these volatile market conditions. The burden of a volatile market thus lies with the industry rather than the controlling agency, which is generally more efficient. However, under volatile market conditions, the ability of the controlling agency to alter the caps will translate into an ability to pick "winners and losers" and thus presents an opportunity for corruption.

In contrast, an emission tax is a price instrument because it fixes the price while the emission level is allowed to vary according to economic activity. A major drawback of an emission tax is that the environmental outcome (e.g. a limit on the amount of emissions) is not guaranteed. On one hand, a tax will remove capital from the industry, suppressing possibly useful economic activity, but conversely, the polluter will not need to hedge as much against future uncertainty since the amount of tax will track with profits. The burden of a volatile market will be borne by the controlling (taxing) agency rather than the industry itself, which is generally less efficient. An advantage is that, given a uniform tax rate and a volatile market, the taxing entity will not be in a position to pick "winners and losers" and the opportunity for corruption will be less.

Assuming no corruption and assuming that the controlling agency and the industry are equally efficient at adapting to volatile market conditions, the best choice depends on the sensitivity of the costs of emission reduction, compared to the sensitivity of the benefits (i.e., climate damage avoided by a reduction) when the level of emission control is varied.

Because there is high uncertainty in the compliance costs of firms, some argue that the optimum choice is the price mechanism. However, the burden of uncertainty cannot be eliminated, and in this case it is shifted to the taxing agency itself.

The overwhelming majority of climate scientists have repeatedly warned of a threshold in atmospheric concentrations of carbon dioxide beyond which a run-away warming effect could take place, with a large possibility of causing irreversible damage. With such a risk, a quantity instrument may be a better choice because the quantity of emissions may be capped with more certainty. However, this may not be true if this risk exists but cannot be attached to a known level of greenhouse gas (GHG) concentration or a known emission pathway.[69]

A third option, known as a safety valve, is a hybrid of the price and quantity instruments. The system is essentially an emission cap and permit trading system but the maximum (or minimum) permit price is capped. Emitters have the choice of either obtaining permits in the marketplace or buying them from the government at a specified trigger price (which could be adjusted over time). The system is sometimes recommended as a way of overcoming the fundamental disadvantages of both systems by giving governments the flexibility to adjust the system as new information comes to light. It can be shown that by setting the trigger price high enough, or the number of permits low enough, the safety valve can be used to mimic either a pure quantity or pure price mechanism.[70]

All three methods are being used as policy instruments to control greenhouse gas emissions: the EU-ETS is a quantity system using the cap and trading system to meet targets set by National Allocation Plans; Denmark has a price system using a carbon tax (World Bank, 2010, p. 218),[88] while China uses the CO2 market price for funding of its Clean Development Mechanism projects, but imposes a safety valve of a minimum price per tonne of CO2.

Carbon leakage

Carbon leakage is the effect that regulation of emissions in one country/sector has on the emissions in other countries/sectors that are not subject to the same regulation.[71] There is no consensus over the magnitude of long-term carbon leakage.[72]

In the Kyoto Protocol, Annex I countries are subject to caps on emissions, but non-Annex I countries are not. Barker et al. (2007) assessed the literature on leakage. The leakage rate is defined as the increase in CO2 emissions outside the countries taking domestic mitigation action, divided by the reduction in emissions of countries taking domestic mitigation action. Accordingly, a leakage rate greater than 100% means that actions to reduce emissions within countries had the effect of increasing emissions in other countries to a greater extent, i.e., domestic mitigation action had actually led to an increase in global emissions.

Estimates of leakage rates for action under the Kyoto Protocol ranged from 5% to 20% as a result of a loss in price competitiveness, but these leakage rates were considered very uncertain.[71] For energy-intensive industries, the beneficial effects of Annex I actions through technological development were considered possibly substantial. However, this beneficial effect had not been reliably quantified. On the empirical evidence they assessed, Barker et al. (2007) concluded that the competitive losses of then-current mitigation actions, e.g., the EU ETS, were not significant.

Under the EU ETS rules Carbon Leakage Exposure Factor is used to determine the volumes of free allocation of emission permits to industrial installations.

Trade

To understand carbon trading, it is important to understand the products that are being traded. The primary product in carbon markets is the trading of GHG emission permits. Under a cap-and-trade system, permits are issued to various entities for the right to emit GHG emissions that meet emission reduction requirement caps.[40]

One of the controversies about carbon mitigation policy is how to "level the playing field" with border adjustments.[73] For example, one component of the American Clean Energy and Security Act (a 2009 bill that did not pass), along with several other energy bills put before US Congress, calls for carbon surcharges on goods imported from countries without cap-and-trade programs. Besides issues of compliance with the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade, such border adjustments presume that the producing countries bear responsibility for the carbon emissions.

A general perception among developing countries is that discussion of climate change in trade negotiations could lead to "green protectionism" by high-income countries (World Bank, 2010, p. 251).[74] Tariffs on imports ("virtual carbon") consistent with a carbon price of $50 per ton of CO2 could be significant for developing countries. World Bank (2010) commented that introducing border tariffs could lead to a proliferation of trade measures where the competitive playing field is viewed as being uneven. Tariffs could also be a burden on low-income countries that have contributed very little to the problem of climate change.

Trading systems

Kyoto Protocol

In 1990, the first Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) report highlighted the imminent threat of climate change and greenhouse gas emission, and diplomatic efforts began to find an international framework within which such emissions could be regulated. In 1997 the Kyoto Protocol was adopted.

The Kyoto Protocol is a 1997 international treaty that came into force in 2005. In the treaty, most developed nations agreed to legally binding targets for their emissions of the six major greenhouse gases.[75] Emission quotas (known as "Assigned amounts") were agreed by each participating 'Annex I' country, with the intention of reducing the overall emissions by 5.2% from their 1990 levels by the end of 2012. Between 1990 and 2012 the original Kyoto Protocol parties reduced their CO2 emissions by 12.5%, which is well beyond the 2012 target of 4.7%. The United States is the only industrialized nation under Annex I that has not ratified the treaty, and is therefore not bound by it. The IPCC has projected that the financial effect of compliance through trading within the Kyoto commitment period will be limited at between 0.1-1.1% of GDP among trading countries.[76]

The agreement was intended to result in industrialized countries' emissions declining in aggregate by 5.2 percent below 1990 levels by the year of 2012. Despite the failure of the United States and Australia to ratify the protocol, the agreement became effective in 2005, once the requirement that 55 Annex I (predominantly industrialized) countries, jointly accounting for 55 percent of 1990 Annex I emissions, ratify the agreement was met.[77]

The Protocol defines several mechanisms ("flexible mechanisms") that are designed to allow Annex I countries to meet their emission reduction commitments (caps) with reduced economic impact.[78]

Under Article 3.3 of the Kyoto Protocol, Annex I Parties may use GHG removals, from afforestation and reforestation (forest sinks) and deforestation (sources) since 1990, to meet their emission reduction commitments.[79]

Annex I Parties may also use International Emissions Trading (IET). Under the treaty, for the 5-year compliance period from 2008 until 2012,[80] nations that emit less than their quota will be able to sell assigned amount units (each AAU

representing an allowance to emit one metric tonne of CO2) to nations that exceed their quotas.[81] It is also possible for Annex I countries to sponsor carbon projects that reduce greenhouse gas emissions in other countries. These projects generate tradable carbon credits that can be used by Annex I countries in meeting their caps. The project-based Kyoto Mechanisms are the Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) and Joint Implementation (JI). There are four such international flexible mechanisms, or Kyoto Mechanism,[82] written in the Kyoto Protocol.

Article 17 if the Protocol authorizes Annex 1 countries that have agreed to the emissions limitations to take part in emissions trading with other Annex 1 Countries.

Article 4 authorizes such parties to implement their limitations jointly, as the member states of the EU have chosen to do.

Article 6 provides that such Annex 1 countries may take part in joint initiatives (JIs) in return for emissions reduction units (ERUs) to be used against their Assigned Amounts.

Art 12 provides for a mechanism known as the clean development mechanism (CDM),[83] under which Annex 1 countries may invest in emissions limitation projects in developing countries and use certified emissions reductions (CERs) generated against their own Assigned Amounts.[18]

The CDM covers projects taking place in non-Annex I countries, while JI covers projects taking place in Annex I countries. CDM projects are supposed to contribute to sustainable development in developing countries, and also generate "real" and "additional" emission savings, i.e., savings that only occur thanks to the CDM project in question (Carbon Trust, 2009, p. 14).[84] Whether or not these emission savings are genuine is, however, difficult to prove (World Bank, 2010, pp. 265–267).[74]

Australia

{{Main|Garnaut Climate Change Review|Carbon Pollution Reduction Scheme|Clean Energy Bill 2011}}

In 2003 the New South Wales (NSW) state government unilaterally established the NSW Greenhouse Gas Abatement Scheme[85] to reduce emissions by requiring electricity generators and large consumers to purchase NSW Greenhouse Abatement Certificates (NGACs). This has prompted the rollout of free energy-efficient compact fluorescent lightbulbs and other energy-efficiency measures, funded by the credits. This scheme has been criticised by the Centre for Energy and Environmental Markets (CEEM) of the UNSW because of its lack of effectiveness in reducing emissions, its lack of transparency and its lack of verification of the additionality of emission reductions.[86]

Both the incumbent Howard Coalition government and the Rudd Labor opposition promised to implement an emissions trading scheme (ETS) before the 2007 federal election. Labor won the election, with the new government proceeding to implement an ETS. The government introduced the Carbon Pollution Reduction Scheme, which the Liberals supported with Malcolm Turnbull as leader. Tony Abbott questioned an ETS, saying the best way to reduce emissions is with a "simple tax".[87] Shortly before the carbon vote, Abbott defeated Turnbull in a leadership challenge, and from there on the Liberals opposed the ETS. This left the government unable to secure passage of the bill and it was subsequently withdrawn.

Julia Gillard defeated Rudd in a leadership challenge and promised not to introduce a carbon tax, but would look to legislate a price on carbon [88] when taking the government to the 2010 election. In the first hung parliament result in 70 years, the government required the support of crossbenchers including the Greens. One requirement for Greens support was a carbon price, which Gillard proceeded with in forming a minority government. A fixed carbon price would proceed to a floating-price ETS within a few years under the plan. The fixed price lent itself to characterisation as a carbon tax and when the government proposed the Clean Energy Bill in February 2011,[89] the opposition claimed it to be a broken election promise.[90]

The bill was passed by the Lower House in October 2011[91] and the Upper House in November 2011.[92] The Liberal Party vowed to overturn the bill if elected.[93] The bill thus resulted in passage of the Clean Energy Act, which possessed a great deal of flexibility in its design and uncertainty over its future.

The Liberal/National coalition government elected in September 2013 has promised to reverse the climate legislation of the previous government.[94] In July 2014, the carbon tax was repealed as well as the Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS) that was to start in 2015.[95]

New Zealand

{{See also|New Zealand Emissions Trading Scheme|Climate change in New Zealand}}

The New Zealand Emissions Trading Scheme (NZ ETS) is a partial-coverage all-free allocation uncapped highly internationally linked emissions trading scheme. The NZ ETS was first legislated in the Climate Change Response (Emissions Trading) Amendment Act 2008 in September 2008 under the Fifth Labour Government of New Zealand[96][97] and then amended in November 2009[98] and in November 2012[99] by the Fifth National Government of New Zealand.

The NZ ETS covers forestry (a net sink), energy (43.4% of total 2010 emissions), industry (6.7% of total 2010 emissions) and waste (2.8% of total 2010 emissions) but not pastoral agriculture (47% of 2010 total emissions).[100] Participants in the NZ ETS must surrender two emissions units (either an international 'Kyoto' unit or a New Zealand-issued unit) for every three tonnes of carbon dioxide equivalent emissions reported or they may choose to buy NZ units from the government at a fixed price of NZ$25.[123]

Individual sectors of the economy have different entry dates when their obligations to report emissions and surrender emission units take effect. Forestry, which contributed net removals of 17.5 Mts of CO2e in 2010 (19% of NZ's 2008 emissions,[101]) entered the NZ ETS on 1 January 2008.[102] The stationary energy, industrial processes and liquid fossil fuel sectors entered the NZ ETS on 1 July 2010. The waste sector (landfill operators) entered on 1 January 2013.[103] Methane and nitrous oxide emissions from pastoral agriculture are not included in the NZ ETS. (From November 2009, agriculture was to enter the NZ ETS on 1 January 2015[104])

The NZ ETS is highly linked to international carbon markets as it allows the importing of most of the Kyoto Protocol emission units. However, as of June 2015, the scheme will effectively transition into a domestic scheme, with restricted access to international Kyoto units (CERs, ERUs and RMUs).[105] The NZ ETS has a domestic unit; the 'New Zealand Unit' (NZU), which is issued by free allocation to emitters, with no auctions intended in the short term.[106] Free allocation of NZUs varies between sectors. The commercial fishery sector (who are not participants) have a free allocation of units on a historic basis.[104] Owners of pre-1990 forests have received a fixed free allocation of units.[102] Free allocation to emissions-intensive industry,[107][108] is provided on an output-intensity basis. For this sector, there is no set limit on the number of units that may be allocated.[109] The number of units allocated to eligible emitters is based on the average emissions per unit of output within a defined 'activity'.[110] Bertram and Terry (2010, p 16) state that as the NZ ETS does not 'cap' emissions, the NZ ETS is not a cap and trade scheme as understood in the economics literature.[111]

Some stakeholders have criticized the New Zealand Emissions Trading Scheme for its generous free allocations of emission units and the lack of a carbon price signal (the Parliamentary Commissioner for the Environment),[112] and for being ineffective in reducing emissions (Greenpeace Aotearoa New Zealand).[113]

The NZ ETS was reviewed in late 2011 by an independent panel, which reported to the Government and public in September 2011.[114]

European Union

{{Main|European Union Emission Trading Scheme}}

The European Union Emission Trading Scheme (or EU ETS) is the largest multi-national, greenhouse gas emissions trading scheme in the world. It is one of the EU's central policy instruments to meet their cap set in the Kyoto Protocol.[115]

After voluntary trials in the UK and Denmark, Phase I began operation in January 2005 with all 15 member states of the European Union participating.[116] The program caps the amount of carbon dioxide that can be emitted from large installations with a net heat supply in excess of 20 MW, such as power plants and carbon intensive factories[117] and covers almost half (46%) of the EU's Carbon Dioxide emissions.[118] Phase I permits participants to trade among themselves and in validated credits from the developing world through Kyoto's Clean Development Mechanism. Credits are gained by investing in clean technologies and low-carbon solutions, and by certain types of emission-saving projects around the world to cover a proportion of their emissions.[119]

During Phases I and II, allowances for emissions have typically been given free to firms, which has resulted in them getting windfall profits.[120] Ellerman and Buchner (2008) suggested that during its first two years in operation, the EU ETS turned an expected increase in emissions of 1%-2% per year into a small absolute decline. Grubb et al. (2009) suggested that a reasonable estimate for the emissions cut achieved during its first two years of operation was 50-100 MtCO2 per year, or 2.5%-5%.[121]

A number of design flaws have limited the effectiveness of the scheme.[115] In the initial 2005-07 period, emission caps were not tight enough to drive a significant reduction in emissions.[120] The total allocation of allowances turned out to exceed actual emissions. This drove the carbon price down to zero in 2007. This oversupply was caused because the allocation of allowances by the EU was based on emissions data from the European Environmental Agency in Copenhagen, which uses a horizontal activity-based emissions definition similar to the United Nations, the EU ETS Transaction log in Brussels, but a vertical installation-based emissions measurement system. This caused an oversupply of 200 million tonnes (10% of market) in the EU ETS in the first phase and collapsing prices.[122]

Phase II saw some tightening, but the use of JI and CDM offsets was allowed, with the result that no reductions in the EU will be required to meet the Phase II cap.[120] For Phase II, the cap is expected to result in an emissions reduction in 2010 of about 2.4% compared to expected emissions without the cap (business-as-usual emissions).[115] For Phase III (2013–20), the European Commission proposed a number of changes, including:

  • Setting an overall EU cap, with allowances then allocated t
  • Tighter limits on the use of offsets;
  • Unlimited banking of allowances between Phases II and III;
  • A move from allowances to auctioning.

In January 2008, Norway, Iceland, and Liechtenstein joined the European Union Emissions Trading System (EU ETS), according to a publication from the European Commission.[123] The Norwegian Ministry of the Environment has also released its draft National Allocation Plan which provides a carbon cap-and-trade of 15 million metric tonnes of CO2, 8 million of which are set to be auctioned.[124] According to the OECD Economic Survey of Norway 2010, the nation "has announced a target for 2008-12 10% below its commitment under the Kyoto Protocol and a 30% cut compared with 1990 by 2020."[125] In 2012, EU-15 emissions was 15.1% below their base year level. Based on figures for 2012 by the European Environment Agency, EU-15 emissions averaged 11.8% below base-year levels during the 2008-2012 period. This means the EU-15 over-achieved its first Kyoto target by a wide margin.[126]

Tokyo, Japan

{{see also|Tokyo Metropolitan Government}}

The Japanese city of Tokyo is like a country in its own right in terms of its energy consumption and GDP. Tokyo consumes as much energy as "entire countries in Northern Europe, and its production matches the GNP of the world's 16th largest country". A scheme to limit carbon emissions launched in April 2010 covers the top 1,400 emitters in Tokyo, and is enforced and overseen by the Tokyo Metropolitan Government.[127][128] Phase 1, which is similar to Japan's scheme, ran until 2015. (Japan had an ineffective voluntary emissions reductions system for years,[129] but no nationwide cap-and-trade program.) Emitters must cut their emissions by 6% or 8% depending on the type of organization; from 2011, those who exceed their limits must buy matching allowances or invest in renewable-energy certificates or offset credits issued by smaller businesses or branch offices.[130] Polluters that fail to comply will be fined up to 500,000 yen plus credits for 1.3 times excess emissions.[131] In its fourth year, emissions were reduced by 23% compared to base-year emissions.[132] In phase 2, (FY2015-FY2019), the target is expected to increase to 15%-17%. The aim is to cut Tokyo's carbon emissions by 25% from 2000 levels by 2020.[130] These emission limits can be met by using technologies such as solar panels and advanced fuel-saving devices.[128]

United States

Sulfur dioxide

{{main|Acid Rain Program}}

An early example of an emission trading system has been the sulfur dioxide (SO2) trading system under the framework of the Acid Rain Program of the 1990 Clean Air Act in the U.S. Under the program, which is essentially a cap-and-trade emissions trading system, SO2 emissions were reduced by 50% from 1980 levels by 2007.[133] Some experts argue that the cap-and-trade system of SO2 emissions reduction has reduced the cost of controlling acid rain by as much as 80% versus source-by-source reduction.[44][134] The SO2 program was challenged in 2004, which set in motion a series of events that led to the 2011 Cross-State Air Pollution Rule (CSAPR). Under the CSAPR, the national SO2 trading program was replaced by four separate trading groups for SO2 and NOx.[135]

SO2 emissions from Acid Rain Program sources have fallen from 17.3 million tons in 1980 to about 7.6 million tons in 2008, a decrease in emissions of 56 percent. A 2014 EPA analysis estimated that implementation of the Acid Rain Program avoided between 20,000 and 50,000 incidences of premature mortality annually due to reductions of ambient PM2.5 concentrations, and between 430 and 2,000 incidences annually due to reductions of ground-level ozone.[168]{{failed verification|date=June 2017}}

Nitrogen oxides

In 2003, the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) began to administer the NOx Budget Trading Program (NBP) under the NOx State Implementation Plan (also known as the "NOx SIP Call"). The NOx Budget Trading Program was a market-based cap and trade program created to reduce emissions of nitrogen oxides (NOx) from power plants and other large combustion sources in the eastern United States. NOx is a prime ingredient in the formation of ground-level ozone (smog), a pervasive air pollution problem in many areas of the eastern United States. The NBP was designed to reduce NOx emissions during the warm summer months, referred to as the ozone season, when ground-level ozone concentrations are highest.[136] In March 2008, EPA again strengthened the 8-hour ozone standard to 0.075 parts per million (ppm) from its previous 0.08 ppm.[137]

Ozone season NOx emissions decreased by 43 percent between 2003 and 2008, even while energy demand remained essentially flat during the same period. CAIR will result in $85 billion to $100 billion in health benefits and nearly $2 billion in visibility benefits per year by 2015 and will substantially reduce premature mortality in the eastern United States.{{citation needed|date=December 2014}}

NOx reductions due to the NOx Budget Trading Program have led to improvements in ozone and PM2.5, saving an estimated 580 to 1,800 lives in 2008.[138]{{failed verification|date=June 2017}}

A 2017 study in the American Economic Review found that the NOx Budget Trading Program decreased NOx emissions and ambient ozone concentrations.[139] The program reduced expenditures on medicine by about 1.5% ($800 million annually) and reduced the mortality rate by up to 0.5% (2,200 fewer premature deaths, mainly among individuals 75 and older).[139]

Volatile organic compounds

In the United States the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) classifies Volatile Organic Compounds (VOCs) as gases emitted from certain solids and liquids that may have adverse health effects.[140] These VOCs include a variety of chemicals that are emitted from a variety of different products.[140] These include products such as gasoline, perfumes, hair spray, fabric cleaners, PVC, and refrigerants; all of which can contain chemicals such as benzene, acetone, methylene chloride, freons, formaldehyde.[141]

VOCs are also monitored by the United States Geological Survey for its presence in groundwater supply.[142] The USGS concluded that many of the nations aquifers are at risk to low-level VOC contamination.[142] The common symptoms of short levels of exposure to VOCs include headaches, nausea, and eye irritation.[143] If exposed for an extended period of time the symptoms include cancer and damage to the central nervous system.[143]

Greenhouse gases (federal)

{{See also|Climate change in the United States|}}

As of 2017, there is no national emissions trading scheme in the United States. Failing to get Congressional approval for such a scheme, President Barack Obama instead acted through the United States Environmental Protection Agency to attempt to adopt through rulemaking the Clean Power Plan, which does not feature emissions trading. (The plan was subsequently challenged and is under review by the administration of President Donald Trump.)

Concerned at the lack of federal action, several states on the east and west coasts have created sub-national cap-and-trade programs.

President Barack Obama in his proposed 2010 United States federal budget wanted to support clean energy development with a 10-year investment of US$15 billion per year, generated from the sale of greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions credits. Under the proposed cap-and-trade program, all GHG emissions credits would have been auctioned off, generating an estimated $78.7 billion in additional revenue in FY 2012, steadily increasing to $83 billion by FY 2019.[144] The proposal was never made law.

The American Clean Energy and Security Act (H.R. 2454), a greenhouse gas cap-and-trade bill, was passed on 26 June 2009, in the House of Representatives by a vote of 219-212. The bill originated in the House Energy and Commerce Committee and was introduced by Representatives Henry A. Waxman and Edward J. Markey.[145] The political advocacy organizations FreedomWorks and Americans for Prosperity, funded by brothers David and Charles Koch of Koch Industries, encouraged the Tea Party movement to focus on defeating the legislation.[146][147] Although cap and trade also gained a significant foothold in the Senate via the efforts of Republican Lindsey Graham, Independent and former Democrat Joe Lieberman, and Democrat John Kerry,[148] the legislation died in the Senate.[149]

State and regional programs

In 2003, New York State proposed and attained commitments from nine Northeast states to form a cap-and-trade carbon dioxide emissions program for power generators, called the Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative (RGGI). This program launched on January 1, 2009 with the aim to reduce the carbon "budget" of each state's electricity generation sector to 10% below their 2009 allowances by 2018.[150]

Also in 2003, U.S. corporations were able to trade CO2 emission allowances on the Chicago Climate Exchange under a voluntary scheme. In August 2007, the Exchange announced a mechanism to create emission offsets for projects within the United States that cleanly destroy ozone-depleting substances.[151]

In 2006, the California Legislature passed the California Global Warming Solutions Act, AB-32, which was signed into law by Governor Arnold Schwarzenegger. Thus far, flexible mechanisms in the form of project based offsets have been suggested for three main project types. The project types include: manure management, forestry, and destruction of ozone-depleted substances. However, a ruling from Judge Ernest H. Goldsmith of San Francisco's Superior Court stated that the rules governing California's cap-and-trade system were adopted without a proper analysis of alternative methods to reduce greenhouse gas emissions.[152] The tentative ruling, issued on 24 January 2011, argued that the California Air Resources Board violated state environmental law by failing to consider such alternatives. If the decision is made final, the state would not be allowed to implement its proposed cap-and-trade system until the California Air Resources Board fully complies with the California Environmental Quality Act.[153]{{update inline|date=June 2017}} California's cap-and-trade program ranks only second to the ETS (European Trading System) carbon market in the world.[154] In 2012, under the auction, the reserve price, which is the price per ton of CO2 permit is $10. Some of the emitters obtain allowances for free, which is for the electric utilities, industrial facilities and natural gas distributors, whereas some of the others have to go to the auction.[155]

In 2014, the Texas legislature approved a 10% reduction for the Highly Reactive Volatile Organic Compound (HRVOC) emission limit.[156] This was followed by a 5% reduction for each subsequent year until a total of 25% percent reduction was achieved in 2017.[156]

In February 2007, five U.S. states and four Canadian provinces joined together to create the Western Climate Initiative (WCI), a regional greenhouse gas emissions trading system.[157] In July 2010, a meeting took place to further outline the cap-and-trade system.[158] In November 2011, Arizona, Montana, New Mexico, Oregon, Utah and Washington withdrew from the WCI.[159][160]

In 1997, the State of Illinois adopted a trading program for volatile organic compounds in most of the Chicago area, called the Emissions Reduction Market System.[161] Beginning in 2000, over 100 major sources of pollution in eight Illinois counties began trading pollution credits.

South Korea

South Korea's national emissions trading scheme officially launched on 1 January 2015, covering 525 entities from 23 sectors. With a three-year cap of 1.8687 billion tCO2e, it now forms the second largest carbon market in the world following the EU ETS. This amounts to roughly two-thirds of the country's emissions. The Korean emissions trading scheme is part of the Republic of Korea's efforts to reduce greenhouse gas emissions by 30% compared to the business-as-usual scenario by 2020.[162]

China

Pollution Permit Trading

In an effort to reverse the adverse consequences of air pollution, in 2006, China started to consider a national pollution permit trading system in order to use market-based mechanisms to incentivize companies to cut pollution.[163] This has been based on a previous pilot project called the Industrial SO2 emission trading pilot scheme, which was launched in 2002. Four provinces, three municipalities and one business entity was involved in this pilot project (also known as the 4+3+1 project). They are Shandong, Shanxi, Jiangsu, Henan, Shanghai, Tianjin, Liuzhou and China Huaneng Group, a state-owned company in the power industry.[164] This pilot project did not turn into a bigger scale inter-provincial trading system, but it stimulated numerous local trading platforms.[164]

In 2014, when the Chinese government started considering a national level pollution permit trading system again, there were more than 20 local pollution permit trading platforms. The Yangtze River Delta region as a whole has also run test trading, but the scale was limited.[165] In the same year, the Chinese government proposed establishing a carbon market, focused on CO2 reduction later in the decade, and it is a separate system from the pollution permit trading.[165]

Carbon Market

China currently emits about 30% of global emission, and it became the largest emitter in the world. When the market launched, it will be the largest carbon market in the world. The initial design of the system targets a scope of 3.5 billion tons of carbon dioxide emissions that come from 1700 installations.[166] It has made a voluntary pledge under the UNFCCC to lower CO2 per unit of GDP by 40 to 45% in 2020 when comparing to the 2005 levels.[167]

In November 2011, China approved pilot tests of carbon trading in seven provinces and cities – Beijing, Chongqing, Shanghai, Shenzhen, Tianjin as well as Guangdong Province and Hubei Province, with different prices in each region.[168] The pilot is intended to test the waters and provide valuable lessons for the design of a national system in the near future. Their successes or failures will, therefore, have far-reaching implications for carbon market development in China in terms of trust in a national carbon trading market. Some of the pilot regions can start trading as early as 2013/2014.[169] National trading is expected to start in 2017, latest in 2020.

The effort to start a national trading system has faced some problems that took longer than expected to solve, mainly in the complicated process of initial data collection to determine the base level of pollution emission.[170] According to the initial design, there will be eight sectors that are first included in the trading system, chemicals, petrochemicals, iron and steel, non-ferrous metals, building materials, paper, power and aviation, but many of the companies involved lacked consistent data.[166] Therefore, by the end of 2017, the allocation of emission quotas have started but it has been limited to only the power sector and will gradually expand, although the operation of the market is yet to begin.[171] In this system, Companies that are involved will be asked to meet target level of reduction and the level will contract gradually.[166]

India

Trading is set to begin in 2014 after a three-year rollout period. It is a mandatory energy efficiency trading scheme covering eight sectors responsible for 54 per cent of India's industrial energy consumption. India has pledged a 20 to 25 per cent reduction in emissions intensity from 2005 levels by 2020. Under the scheme, annual efficiency targets will be allocated to firms. Tradable energy-saving permits will be issued depending on the amount of energy saved during a target year.[169]

Renewable energy certificates

{{Main|Renewable Energy Certificates}}

Renewable Energy Certificates (occasionally referred to as or "green tags" [citation required]), are a largely unrelated form of market-based instruments that are used to achieve renewable energy targets, which may be environmentally motivated (like emissions reduction targets), but may also be motivated by other aims, such as energy security or industrial policy.

Carbon market

{{Main|Carbon emission trading}}

Carbon emissions trading is emissions trading specifically for carbon dioxide (calculated in tonnes of carbon dioxide equivalent or tCO2e) and currently makes up the bulk of emissions trading. It is one of the ways countries can meet their obligations under the Kyoto Protocol to reduce carbon emissions and thereby mitigate global warming.

{{See also|personal carbon trading|carbon offset}}

Market trend

Trading can be done directly between buyers and sellers, through several organised exchanges or through the many intermediaries active in the carbon market. The price of allowances is determined by supply and demand. As many as 40 million allowances have been traded per day. In 2012, 7.9 billion allowances were traded with a total value of €56 billion.[119] Carbon emissions trading declined in 2013, and is expected to decline in 2014.[172]

According to the World Bank's Carbon Finance Unit, 374 million metric tonnes of carbon dioxide equivalent (tCO2e) were exchanged through projects in 2005, a 240% increase relative to 2004 (110 mtCO2e)[173] which was itself a 41% increase relative to 2003 (78 mtCO2e).[174]

Global carbon markets have shrunk in value by 60% since 2011, but are expected to rise again in 2014.[175]

In terms of dollars, the World Bank has estimated that the size of the carbon market was US$11 billion in 2005, $30 billion in 2006,[173] and $64 billion in 2007.[176]

The Marrakesh Accords of the Kyoto protocol defined the international trading mechanisms and registries needed to support trading between countries (sources can buy or sell allowances on the open market. Because the total number of allowances is limited by the cap, emission reductions are assured.).[177] Allowance trading now occurs between European countries and Asian countries. However, while the US as a nation did not ratify the protocol, many of its states are developing cap-and-trade systems and considering ways to link them together, nationally and internationally, to find the lowest costs and improve liquidity of the market.[178] However, these states also wish to preserve their individual integrity and unique features. For example, in contrast to other Kyoto-compliant systems, some states propose other types of greenhouse gas sources, different measurement methods, setting a maximum on the price of allowances, or restricting access to CDM projects. Creating instruments that are not fungible (exchangeable) could introduce instability and make pricing difficult. Various proposals for linking these systems across markets are being investigated, and this is being coordinated by the International Carbon Action Partnership (ICAP).[178][179]

Business reaction

In 2008, Barclays Capital predicted that the new carbon market would be worth $70 billion worldwide that year.[180] The voluntary offset market, by comparison, is projected to grow to about $4bn by 2010.[181]

23 multinational corporations came together in the G8 Climate Change Roundtable, a business group formed at the January 2005 World Economic Forum. The group included Ford, Toyota, British Airways, BP and Unilever. On June 9, 2005 the Group published a statement stating the need to act on climate change and stressing the importance of market-based solutions. It called on governments to establish "clear, transparent, and consistent price signals" through "creation of a long-term policy framework" that would include all major producers of greenhouse gases.[182] By December 2007, this had grown to encompass 150 global businesses.[183]

Business in the UK have come out strongly in support of emissions trading as a key tool to mitigate climate change, supported by NGOs.[184] However, not all businesses favor a trading approach. On December 11, 2008, Rex Tillerson, the CEO of Exxonmobil, said a carbon tax is "a more direct, more transparent and more effective approach" than a cap-and-trade program, which he said, "inevitably introduces unnecessary cost and complexity". He also said that he hoped that the revenues from a carbon tax would be used to lower other taxes so as to be revenue neutral.[185]

The International Air Transport Association, whose 230 member airlines comprise 93% of all international traffic, position is that trading should be based on "benchmarking", setting emissions levels based on industry averages, rather than "grandfathering", which would use individual companies’ previous emissions levels to set their future permit allowances. They argue grandfathering "would penalise airlines that took early action to modernise their fleets, while a benchmarking approach, if designed properly, would reward more efficient operations".[186]

Measuring, reporting, verification

{{Refimprove section|date=September 2009}}

Assuring compliance with an emissions trading scheme requires measuring, reporting and verification (MRV).[187] Measurements are needed at each operator or installation. These measurements are reported to a regulator. For greenhouse gases, all trading countries maintain an inventory of emissions at national and installation level; in addition, trading groups within North America maintain inventories at the state level through The Climate Registry. For trading between regions, these inventories must be consistent, with equivalent units and measurement techniques.[188]

In some industrial processes, emissions can be physically measured by inserting sensors and flowmeters in chimneys and stacks, but many types of activity rely on theoretical calculations instead of measurement. Depending on local legislation, measurements may require additional checks and verification by government or third party auditors, prior or post submission to the local regulator.

Enforcement

In contrast to an ordinary market, in a pollution market the amount purchased is not necessarily the amount 'consumed' (= the amount of pollution emitted). A firm might buy a small amount of allowances but emit a much larger amount of pollution. This creates a troublesome moral hazard problem.

This problem may be solved by a centralized regulator. The regulator should perform Measuring, Reporting and Verification (MRV) of the actual pollution levels, and enforce the allowances.[189] Without effective MRV and enforcement, the value of allowances diminishes. Enforcement methods include fines and sanctions for polluters that have exceeded their allowances. Concerns include the cost of MRV and enforcement, and the risk that facilities may lie about actual emissions. The net effect of a corrupt reporting system or poorly managed or financed regulator may be a discount on emission costs, and a hidden increase in actual emissions.

According to Nordhaus, strict enforcement of the Kyoto Protocol is likely to be observed in those countries and industries covered by the EU ETS.[190]

Ellerman and Buchner commented on the European Commission's (EC's) role in enforcing scarcity of permits within the EU ETS.[191]

This was done by the EC's reviewing the total number of permits that member states proposed that their industries be allocated. Based on institutional and enforcement considerations, Kruger et al. suggested that emissions trading within developing countries might not be a realistic goal in the near-term.[192]

Burniaux et al. argued that due to the difficulty in enforcing international rules against sovereign states, development of the carbon market would require negotiation and consensus-building.[193]

An alternative to centralized regulation is distributed regulation, in which the firms themselves are induced to inspect the other firms and report their misbehavior. It is possible to implement such systems in subgame perfect equilibrium. Moore and Repullo[194] present an implementation with unbounded fines; Kahana and Mealem and Nitzan[195] present an implementation with bounded fines. Their work extends the work of Duggan and Roberts[196] by adding a second component which takes care of the moral hazard.

Criticism

Emissions trading has been criticised for a variety of reasons.

For example, in the popular science magazine New Scientist, Lohmann (2006) argued that trading pollution allowances should be avoided as a climate stabilization policy for several reasons. First, climate change requires more radical changes than previous pollution trading schemes such as the US SO2 market. It requires reorganizing society and technology to "leave most remaining fossil fuels safely underground". Carbon trading schemes have tended to reward the heaviest polluters with 'windfall profits' when they are granted enough carbon credits to match historic production. Expensive long-term structural changes will not be made if there are cheaper sources of carbon credits which are often available from less developed countries, where they may be generated by local polluters at the expense of local communities.[197]

Research by Preston Teeter and Jorgen Sandberg has shown that the flexibility, and thus complexity, inherent in cap and trade schemes has resulted in a great deal of policy uncertainty surrounding these schemes. Such uncertainty has beset such schemes in Australia, Canada, China, the EU, India, Japan, New Zealand, and the US. As a result of this uncertainty, organizations have little incentive to innovate and comply, resulting in an ongoing battle of stakeholder contestation for the past two decades.[7]

Lohmann (2006b) supported conventional regulation, green taxes, and energy policies that are "justice-based" and "community-driven."[198] According to Carbon Trade Watch (2009), carbon trading has had a "disastrous track record." The effectiveness of the EU ETS was criticized, and it was argued that the CDM had routinely favoured "environmentally ineffective and socially unjust projects."[199]

Annie Leonard's 2009 documentary The Story of Cap and Trade criticized carbon emissions trading for the free permits to major polluters giving them unjust advantages, cheating in connection with carbon offsets, and as a distraction from the search for other solutions.[200]

Offsets

Forest campaigner Jutta Kill (2006) of European environmental group FERN argued that offsets for emission reductions were not substitute for actual cuts in emissions. Kill stated that "[carbon] in trees is temporary: Trees can easily release carbon into the atmosphere through fire, disease, climatic changes, natural decay and timber harvesting."[201]

Permit supply level

Regulatory agencies run the risk of issuing too many emission credits, which can result in a very low price on emission permits.[120] This reduces the incentive that permit-liable firms have to cut back their emissions. On the other hand, issuing too few permits can result in an excessively high permit price.[202] This an argument for a hybrid instrument having a price-floor, i.e., a minimum permit price, and a price-ceiling, i.e., a limit on the permit price. However, a price-ceiling (safety value) removes the certainty of a particular quantity limit of emissions.[203]

Permit allocation versus auctioning

If polluters receive emission permits for free ("grandfathering"), this may be a reason for them not to cut their emissions because if they do they will receive fewer permits in the future.[204]

This perverse incentive can be alleviated if permits are auctioned, i.e., sold to polluters, rather than giving them the permits for free.[202] Auctioning is a method for distributing emission allowances in a cap-and-trade system whereby allowances are sold to the highest bidder. Revenues from auctioning go to the government and can be used for development of sustainable technology[205] or to cut distortionary taxes, thus improving the efficiency of the overall cap policy.[206]

On the other hand, allocating permits can be used as a measure to protect domestic firms who are internationally exposed to competition.[202] This happens when domestic firms compete against other firms that are not subject to the same regulation. This argument in favor of allocation of permits has been used in the EU ETS, where industries that have been judged to be internationally exposed, e.g., cement and steel production, have been given permits for free).[207]

This method of distribution may be combined with other forms of allowance distribution.[58]

Distributional effects

The US Congressional Budget Office (CBO, 2009) examined the potential effects of the American Clean Energy and Security Act on US households.[208] This act relies heavily on the free allocation of permits. The Bill was found to protect low-income consumers, but it was recommended that the Bill be made more efficient by reducing welfare provisions for corporations, and more resources be made available for consumer relief.

Linking

Distinct cap-and-trade systems can be linked together through the mutual or unilateral recognition of emissions allowances for compliance. Linking systems creates a larger carbon market, which can reduce overall compliance costs, increase market liquidity and generate a more stable carbon market.[209][210] Linking systems can also be politically symbolic as it shows willingness to undertake a common effort to reduce GHG emissions.[211] Some scholars have argued that linking may provide a starting point for developing a new, bottom-up international climate policy architecture, whereby multiple unique systems successively link their various systems.[212][213]

In 2014, the U.S. state of California and the Canadian province of Québec successfully linked their systems. In 2015, the provinces of Ontario and Manitoba agreed to join the linked system between Quebec and California.[214] On 22 September 2017, the premiers of Quebec and Ontario, and the Governor of California, signed the formal agreement establishing the linkage.[215]

The International Carbon Action Partnership brings together regional, national and sub-national governments and public authorities from around the world to discuss important issues in the design of emissions trading schemes (ETS) and the way forward to a global carbon market. 30 national and subnational jurisdictions have joined ICAP as members since its establishment in 2007.[216]

See also

{{Portal|Global warming|Ecology|Environment}}{{Div col}}
  • Acid Rain Retirement Fund
  • AP 42 Compilation of Air Pollutant Emission Factors
  • Asia-Pacific Emissions Trading Forum
  • Cap and Dividend
  • Cap and Share
  • Carbon credit
  • Carbon emissions reporting
  • Carbon finance
  • Carbon offset
  • Emission standard
  • Energy law
  • Flexible Mechanisms
  • Green certificate
  • Green investment scheme
  • Individual and political action on climate change
  • Low-carbon economy
  • Low carbon power generation / Renewable energy
  • Mitigation of global warming
  • Mobile Emission Reduction Credit (MERC)
  • Personal carbon trading
  • Pigovian tax
  • Public Smog
  • Reducing emissions from deforestation and forest degradation
  • Tradable smoking pollution permits
  • Verified Carbon Standard
{{div col end}}

References

1. ^{{Cite journal|first=Robert N. |last=Stavins |date = November 2001|accessdate=2010-05-20 |title=Experience with Market-Based Environmental Policy Instruments |url= http://www.rff.org/documents/RFF-DP-01-58.pdf |journal= Discussion Paper 01-58 |publisher= Resources for the Future |location=Washington, D.C. |quote= Market-based instruments are regulations that encourage behavior through market signals rather than through explicit directives regarding pollution control levels or methods }}
2. ^{{cite web|title=Allowance Trading|url=http://www.epa.gov/airmarkets/trading/|publisher=U.S Environment Protection Agency|accessdate=Oct 21, 2014}}
3. ^{{cite journal |author1=Judson Jaffe |author2=Matthew Ranson |author3=Robert N. Stavins |year=2009 |url= http://www.boalt.org/elq/documents/elq36-4-01-jaffe-2009-1209.pdf |title=Linking Tradable Permit Systems: A Key Element of Emerging International Climate Policy Architecture |journal= Ecology Law Quarterly |volume=36 |issue=789 |accessdate=2010-08-25}}
4. ^{{cite journal |doi=10.1093/oxrep/19.3.400 |author= Tietenberg, Tom |year=2003 |url= http://oxrep.oxfordjournals.org/cgi/reprint/19/3/400?ijkey=324rjCyD25Jfk&keytype=ref |title=The Tradable-Permits Approach to Protecting the Commons: Lessons for Climate Change |journal= Oxford Review of Economic Policy |volume=19 |issue=3 |pages= 400–419 |accessdate=2010-08-25 }}
5. ^{{Cite journal|author=Stavins, Robert N. |date=November 2001 |url=http://www.rff.org/documents/RFF-DP-01-58.pdf |title=Experience with Market-Based Environmental Policy Instruments |series=Discussion Paper 01-58 |publisher=Resources for the Future |location= Washington, D.C. |accessdate=2010-08-25 }}
6. ^{{cite web|url=http://www.oecd.org/tax/treaties/report-emissions-permits.pdf|title=Tax Treaty Issues Related to Emissions Permits/Credits|publisher=OECD|accessdate=25 Oct 2014}}
7. ^{{Cite journal|last=Teeter|first=Preston|last2=Sandberg|first2=Jorgen|date=2016|title=Constraining or Enabling Green Capability Development? How Policy Uncertainty Affects Organizational Responses to Flexible Environmental Regulations|journal=British Journal of Management|volume=28|issue=4|pages=649–665|doi=10.1111/1467-8551.12188|pmid=}}
8. ^EU Emissions Trading System (EU ETS) {{webarchive |url=https://web.archive.org/web/20091214041527/http://www.decc.gov.uk/en/content/cms/what_we_do/change_energy/tackling_clima/emissions/eu_ets/eu_ets.aspx |date=December 14, 2009 }}. UK Department of Energy and Climate Change. Retrieved 2009-01-19.
9. ^"Emissions trading schemes around the world", Parliament of Australia, 2013.
10. ^{{cite web | url = http://www.epa.gov/airmarkets/ | title = USEPA's Clean Air Markets web site |publisher=US EPA |accessdate=2009-11-03}}
11. ^{{Cite web|url=http://www.nearzero.org/wp/2017/11/10/californias-climate-emissions-are-falling-but-cap-and-trade-is-not-the-cause/|title=California's climate emissions are falling, but cap-and-trade is not the cause {{!}} Near Zero|access-date=2019-01-04}}
12. ^{{Cite web|url=https://news.berkeley.edu/2018/07/10/californias-cap-and-trade-air-quality-benefits-go-mostly-out-of-state/|title=California's cap-and-trade air quality benefits go mostly out of state|last=S|first=Robert|last2=ers|date=2018-07-10|website=Berkeley News|access-date=2019-01-04|last3=July 10|first3=Media relations{{!}}|last4=2018July 13|last5=2018}}
13. ^{{cite journal|last=Montgomery|first=W.D|date=December 1972|title=Markets in Licenses and Efficient Pollution Control Programs|journal=Journal of Economic Theory|volume=5|issue=3|pages=395–418|doi=10.1016/0022-0531(72)90049-X}}
14. ^{{cite web|url=http://www.epa.gov/airmarkets/cap-trade/docs/ctresults.pdf|title=Cap and Trade: Acid Rain Program Results|date=2014-08-12|publisher=Environmental Protection Agency|archiveurl=https://web.archive.org/web/20150924032248/http://www.epa.gov/airmarkets/cap-trade/docs/ctresults.pdf|archivedate=24 September 2015|deadurl=yes}}
15. ^{{Cite web|url=https://www.foodandwaterwatch.org/sites/default/files/ibsp_1711_ejpaytopollute-webfin2_0.pdf|website=www.foodandwaterwatch.org|access-date=2019-01-04}}
16. ^{{Cite journal|last=Chestnut|first=Lauraine G.|last2=Mills|first2=David M.|date=November 2005|title=A fresh look at the benefits and costs of the US acid rain program|journal=Journal of Environmental Management|volume=77|issue=3|pages=252–266|citeseerx=10.1.1.364.2934|doi=10.1016/j.jenvman.2005.05.014|issn=0301-4797|pmid=16171931}}
17. ^Cap and Trade 101, Center for American Progress, January 16, 2008.
18. ^Boswall, J. and Lee, R. (2002). Economics, ethics and the environment. London: Cavendish. pp.62–66.
19. ^{{cite web|title=Cap and Trade 101|url=http://www.epa.gov/captrade/captrade-101.html|publisher=United States Environmental Protection Agency|accessdate=27 October 2014}}
20. ^O'Sullivan, Arthur, and Steven M. Sheffrin. Economics: Principles in Action. Upper Saddle River, New Jersey, 2003. {{ISBN|0-13-063085-3}}
21. ^{{cite web|title=How cap and trade works|url=http://www.edf.org/climate/how-cap-and-trade-works|publisher=Environmental Defense Fund|accessdate=27 October 2014}}
22. ^{{cite web|url=http://report.mitigation2014.org/drafts/final-draft-postplenary/ipcc_wg3_ar5_final-draft_postplenary_chapter13.pdf |title=International Cooperation: Agreements and Instruments |accessdate=2014-11-10 |deadurl=yes |archiveurl=https://web.archive.org/web/20140929140547/http://report.mitigation2014.org/drafts/final-draft-postplenary/ipcc_wg3_ar5_final-draft_postplenary_chapter13.pdf |archivedate=2014-09-29 }}
23. ^Burton, Ellison, and William Sanjour (1967) An Economic Analysis of the Control of Sulphur Oxides Air Pollution DHEW Program Analysis Report No. 1967-69 Washington, D.C.: Ernst and Ernst.
24. ^Burton, Ellison, and William Sanjour. (1968). A Cost-Effectiveness Study of Particulate and SOx Emission Control in the New York Metropolitan Area. NTIS: PB-227 121/1. Contract Number: PH-86-68-37. Washington, D.C.: Ernst and Ernst.
25. ^Burton, Ellison, and William Sanjour. (1969). A Cost-Effectiveness Study of Air Pollution Abatement in the Greater Kansas City Area. NTIS: PB-227 116/1. Washington, D.C.: Ernst and Ernst.
26. ^Burton, Ellison, and William Sanjour. (1969). A Cost-effectiveness Study of Air Pollution Abatement in the National Capital Area. NAPCA Contract No. PH 86-68-37, NTIS: PB227110. Washington, D.C.: Ernst and Ernst.
27. ^Burton, Ellison, and William Sanjour. (1970). Applications of Cost-Effectiveness Analysis to Air Pollution Control. DHEW Contract No. CPA 22-69-17. Washington, D.C.: Ernst and Ernst.
28. ^{{cite journal | last1 = Burton | first1 = E. S. | last2 = Sanjour | first2 = William | year = 1970 | title = A Simulation Approach to Air Pollution Abatement Program Planning | url = | journal = Socio-Economic Planning Science | volume = 4 | issue = | pages = 147–150 | doi=10.1016/0038-0121(70)90036-4}}
29. ^Burton, Ellison S., Edward H. Pechan III, and William Sanjour. (1973). A Survey of Air Pollution Control Models. Rolf A. Deininger, ed. Ann Arbor: Ann Arbor Science Publishers.
30. ^{{cite journal | last1 = Burton | first1 = Ellison S. | last2 = Edward | first2 = H. Pechan III | last3 = Sanjour | first3 = William | year = 1973 | title = Solving the Air Pollution Control Puzzle | url = | journal = Environmental Science and Technology | volume = 7 | issue = 5| page = 412 | doi=10.1021/es60077a011| pmid = 22283532 }}
31. ^U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. (1972). The Economics of Clean Air, Annual Report of the Environmental Protection Agency to the Congress of the United States. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.
32. ^{{cite journal | last1 = Voss | first1 = Jan-Peter | year = 2007 | title = Innovation processes in governance: the development of emissions trading as a new policy instrument | url = | journal = Science and Public Policy | volume = 34 | issue = 5| pages = 329–343 | doi=10.3152/030234207x228584}}
33. ^{{cite journal |last=Coase |first=Ronald H. |year=1960 |title=The Problem of Social Cost |journal=Journal of Law and Economics |volume=3 |issue=1 |pages=1–44 |jstor= |doi=10.1086/466560 |title-link=The Problem of Social Cost }}
34. ^Crocker, T. D. (1966). The Structuring of Atmospheric Pollution Control Systems. The Economics of Air Pollution. H. Wolozin. New York, W. W. Norton & Co.: 61–86.
35. ^{{cite journal | last1 = Dales | first1 = John H | year = 1968 | title = Land, Water, and Ownership | journal = The Canadian Journal of Economics | volume = 1 | issue = 4| pages = 791–804 | jstor=133706| doi = 10.2307/133706 }}
36. ^{{cite web|title=The Clean Development Mechanism: A Review of the First International Offset Program|date=March 2011|url=http://www.c2es.org/docUploads/clean-development-mechanism-review-of-first-international-offset-program.pdf |last1=Gillenwater|first1=Michael|last2=Seres|first2=Stephen|publisher=Pew Center on Global Climate Change|page=6|accessdate=26 November 2016}}
37. ^Coniff, Richard (Aug. 2009). "The Political History of Cap and Trade". Smithsonian Magazine. Retrieved 1-13-2011
38. ^Grimeaud, D, ‘An overview of the policy and legal aspects of the international climate change regime’ (2001) 9(2) Environmental Liability 39.
39. ^Stewart, R, "Economic incentives for environmental protection: opportunities and obstacles", in Revesz, R; Sands, P; Stewart, R (eds.), Environment Law, the Economy and Sustainable Development, 2000, Cambridge University Press.
40. ^{{cite journal|last1=Roos|first1=Joseph A.|last2=Barber|first2=Valerie|last3=Brackley|first3=Allen M.|title=Cap and Trade: Offsets and Implications for Alaska|date=March 2011|url=http://www.arlis.org/docs/vol1/C/713310520.pdf|accessdate=27 October 2014}}
41. ^{{cite web|url=http://uk.reuters.com/article/2014/08/31/china-carbontrading-idUKL3N0R107420140831|title=China's national carbon market to start in 2016 -official|work=Reuters UK|accessdate=25 September 2015}}
42. ^{{cite book|last1=Diesendorf|first1=Mark|title=Sustainable Energy Solutions for Climate Change|date=July 14, 2014|publisher=Routledge}}
43. ^{{cite web |url=http://garnautreview.org.au/update-2011/update-papers/up6-key-points.html |title=Key points: Update Paper 6: Carbon pricing and reducing Australia's emissions |date=17 March 2011 |work=Garnaut Climate Change Review |accessdate=16 July 2013 }}
44. ^{{cite journal|last=Stavins|first=Robert N|year=1998|title=What Can We Learn from the Grand Policy Experiment? Lessons from SO2 Allowance Trading|journal=The Journal of Economic Perspectives|series=3|publisher=American Economic Association|volume=12|issue=3|pages=69–88|doi=10.1257/jep.12.3.69|jstor=2647033}}
45. ^Bryner, Gary C. Blue Skies, Green Politics: the Clean Air Act of 1990. Washington, D.C.:Congressional Quarterly Inc., 1951
46. ^Cox, Stan (2013). [https://thenewpress.com/books/any-way-you-slice-it "Any way you slice it: The past, present and future of rationing"]. New Press Books.
47. ^Hall, JV and Walton, AL, "A case study in pollution markets: dismal science US. Dismal reality" (1996) XIV Contemporary Economic Policy 67.
48. ^{{cite web|url=http://www.oecd.org/tax/treaties/report-emissions-permits.pdf|title=Tax Treaty Issues Related to Emissions Permits/Credits|publisher=OECD|accessdate=22 November 2014}}
49. ^{{cite news|url=http://news.nationalgeographic.com/news/news/energy/2010/11/101103-chicago-climate-exchange-cap-and-trade-election/|title=A U.S. Cap-And-Trade Experiment to End|last=Lavelle|first=Marianne|date=November 3, 2010|newspaper=National Geographic|accessdate=November 7, 2010}}
50. ^{{cite press release|url=http://www.highbeam.com/doc/1G1-184638199.html|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20110501114248/http://www.highbeam.com/doc/1G1-184638199.html|dead-url=yes|archive-date=2011-05-01|title=CantorCO2e Launches First Internet CER Auction|publisher=CantorCO2e|date=2008-09-09|accessdate=2010-01-27}}
51. ^{{cite web|url=http://www.carbonplace.eu|title=Carbon Place . EU - Market with carbon credits - EUA, CER, ERU, VER, AAU-S, AAU-G|accessdate=25 September 2015}}
52. ^{{cite news|url=https://www.nytimes.com/2007/06/20/business/worldbusiness/20iht-money.4.6234700.html?_r=1|title=Carbon trading: Where greed is green|last=Kanter|first=James|date=2007-06-20|newspaper=The New York Times|accessdate=2010-01-27}}
53. ^"[https://www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/content/article/2009/06/24/AR2009062403648.html Majority of Poll Respondents Say U.S. Should Limit Greenhouse Gases]", Washington Post. 25 June 2009.
54. ^"[https://blogs.wsj.com/environmentalcapital/2009/08/11/poll-position-new-zogby-poll-shows-71-support-for-waxman-markey/ Poll Position: New Zogby Poll Shows 71% Support for Waxman-Markey]", Wall Street Journal. 11 Aug. 2009
55. ^"Poll: Americans Support Strong Climate, Energy Policies",Yale Climate & Energy Institute {{webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20120128201527/http://climate.yale.edu/news/poll-americans-support-strong-climate-energy-policies |date=2012-01-28 }}
56. ^{{cite journal|last1=Roberts|first1=David|title=What can we learn from polls on cap-and-trade?|journal=Grist|date=26 Jun 2009|url=http://grist.org/article/2009-06-25-polls-cap-and-trade/|accessdate=27 October 2014}}
57. ^"IBD editorial board claims that cap-and-trade is unpopular in America", PolitiFact
58. ^{{cite web |publisher=Center for Climate and Energy Solutions |title=Cap and Trade: Key Terms Glossary |work=Climate Change 101 |date=January 2011 |url=http://www.c2es.org/docUploads/climate101-captrade.pdf|accessdate=27 October 2014 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20171005153958/http://www.c2es.org/docUploads/climate101-captrade.pdf |archive-date=2017-10-05 |dead-url=yes}}
59. ^{{Cite journal |last=Chomitz |first=Kenneth M. |year=1999 |title=Evaluating Carbon Offsets from Forestry and Energy Projects: How Do They Compare? |ssrn=630729 |publisher=World Bank |series=Policy Research Working Paper Series |volume=2357}}
60. ^{{cite book |last1=Rosen |last2=Gayer |first1=Harvey S. |first2=Ted |title=Public Finance |year=2008 |publisher=McGraw-Hill Irwin |location=New York |isbn=978-0-07-351128-3 |pages=90–94}}
61. ^{{Cite book|title = Carbon Tax and Cap-and-trade Tools : Market-based Approaches for Controlling Greenhouse Gases|last = Burney|first = Nelson E.|publisher = Nova Science Publishers, Inc.|year = 2010|isbn = 9781608761371|location = New York|pages = }}
62. ^{{cite journal|last1=Durning|first1=Alan|title=carBon tax vS. cap and trade|journal=Cap and Trade 101 a Federal Climate Policy Primer|date=July 2009|page=28|url=http://www.sightline.org/wp-content/uploads/downloads/2012/02/Cap-Trade_online.pdf|accessdate=27 October 2014|deadurl=yes|archiveurl=https://web.archive.org/web/20140707153526/http://www.sightline.org/wp-content/uploads/downloads/2012/02/Cap-Trade_online.pdf|archivedate=7 July 2014}}
63. ^Calel, Raphael, "The Language of Climate Change Policy", 2010.
64. ^{{cite journal|year=2012|author1=Yujie Lu |author2=Xinyuan Zhu |author3=Qingbin Cui |title=Effectiveness and equity implications of carbon policies in the United States construction industry|journal=Building and Environment|volume=49|pages=259–269|publisher=Elsevier Ltd.|doi=10.1016/j.buildenv.2011.10.002}}
65. ^{{Cite journal|title=Estimating Offset Supply in a Cap-and-Trade Program|url=http://www.nationalaglawcenter.org/wp-content/uploads/assets/crs/RL34705.pdf|date=April 16, 2010|first=Jonathan L.|last=Ramseur|publisher=Congressional Research Service|page=1|mode=cs2|accessdate=February 15, 2011}}
66. ^Map: Pollution hotspots, BBC map of areas that suffer from intense local pollution, BBC News, 2004-12-13. Retrieved 2009-10-19.
67. ^{{cite web |url=http://www.chicagoclimatex.com/ |title=Chicago Climate Exchange prices |publisher=Chicagoclimatex.com |date=2009-08-04 |accessdate=2009-11-03 |deadurl=yes |archiveurl=https://web.archive.org/web/20091105001705/http://www.chicagoclimatex.com/ |archivedate=2009-11-05 }}
68. ^{{cite journal |doi=10.2307/2296698 |last=Weitzman |first=M. L. |title=Prices vs. Quantities |journal=Review of Economic Studies | volume =41 |issue= 4 |date=October 1974 |pages=477–491 |jstor=2296698 }}
69. ^{{Cite journal | last = Philibert | first = Cédric | title = Certainty versus ambition economic efficiency in mitigating climate change | journal = International Energy Agency Working Paper Series | volume = LTO/2006/03 | issue = | pages = | publisher = International Energy Agency/OECD | location = Paris | date = October 2006 | url =http://www.iea.org/textbase/papers/2006/certainty_ambition.pdf | issn = | doi = | accessdate =2010-01-24 }}
70. ^{{cite journal |last=Jacoby |first=D.H. |last2=Ellerman |first2=A.D. | title =The safety valve and climate policy |journal=Energy Policy | volume =32 |issue=4 |pages=481–49 |publisher=|date=March 2004 | doi = 10.1016/S0301-4215(03)00150-2 |hdl=1721.1/3561 }}
71. ^{{cite book|year=2007|chapter=Mitigation from a cross-sectoral perspective|title=Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change|editor=B. Metz|publisher=IPCC|author=Barker, T.|chapter-url=http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg3/en/ch11.html|accessdate=2010-04-05|display-authors=etal|display-editors=etal}}
72. ^{{cite book|year=1996|author=Goldemberg, J.|page=31|chapter=Introduction: scope of the assessment|title=Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change |editor=J.P. Bruce|publisher=IPCC|chapter-url=http://www.ipcc.ch/ipccreports/sar/wg_III/ipcc_sar_wg_III_full_report.pdf|isbn=978-0-521-56854-8|doi=10.2277/0521568544|display-authors=etal|display-editors=etal}}
73. ^{{cite book | last = Houser | first = Trevor | authorlink = |author2=Rob Bradley |author3=Britt Childs Staley |author4=Jake Werksman |author5=Robert Heilmayr | title = Leveling The Carbon Playing Field: International Competition and U.S. Climate Policy Design | publisher = Peterson Institute for International Economics | year = 2008 | location = | pages = | url = http://www.wri.org/publication/leveling-the-carbon-playing-field | doi = | isbn = }}
74. ^{{cite web|year=2010|title=World Development Report 2010: Development and Climate Change|publisher=World Bank|url= http://www-wds.worldbank.org/external/default/WDSContentServer/IW3P/IB/2010/08/16/000334955_20100816043111/Rendered/PDF/530770WDR020101Official0Use0Only161.pdf|accessdate=2010-04-06}}
75. ^{{cite web|url=http://unfccc.int/kyoto_protocol/items/2830.php|title=Kyoto Protocol|publisher=UNFCCC|accessdate=2009-09-16}}
76. ^{{cite web|url=http://www.mnp.nl/ipcc/docs/FAR/Approved%20SPM%20WGIII_0705rev5.pdf|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20070518152103/http://www.mnp.nl/ipcc/docs/FAR/Approved%20SPM%20WGIII_0705rev5.pdf|dead-url=yes|archive-date=2007-05-18|title=Climate Change 2007: Mitigation of Climate Change, Summary for Policymakers from IPCC Fourth Assessment Report|pages=Item 25, page 33|publisher=Working Group III, IPCC|date=2007-05-04|accessdate=2007-05-10}}
77. ^{{cite journal|last1=Robert W.|first1=Hahn|title=The effect of Allowance Allocations on Cap-and-Trade System Performance|journal=Journal of Law and Economics|date=November 2011|volume=54|issue=4|url=http://www.hks.harvard.edu/fs/rstavins/Papers/Hahn%20&%20Stavins%20in%20Journal%20of%20Law%20&%20Economics.pdf|accessdate=November 22, 2014}}
78. ^{{cite book |year = 2007 |chapter = Glossary |title = Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change |editor = B. Metz |display-editors = etal |publisher = IPCC |chapter-url = http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg3/en/annex1sglossary-j-p.html |accessdate = 2010-04-23 |deadurl = yes |archiveurl = https://web.archive.org/web/20100503041746/http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg3/en/annex1sglossary-j-p.html |archivedate = 2010-05-03 |df =}}
79. ^{{cite web |url=http://unfccc.int/methods_and_science/lulucf/items/4129.php |title=LULUCF under the Kyoto Protocol |publisher=UNFCCC |accessdate=2010-04-28 }}
80. ^{{cite web|url=http://unfccc.int/kyoto_protocol/background/items/3145.php|title=UNFCCC Countries 1990 to 2012 emissions targets|publisher=UNFCCC|date=2008-05-14|accessdate=2009-11-03}}
81. ^{{cite web|url=http://unfccc.int/kyoto_protocol/mechanisms/emissions_trading/items/2731.php|title=Emissions Trading|publisher=UNFCCC|accessdate=2009-09-16}}
82. ^Yamin, F, Burniaux, J-M ad Nentjes, A, "Kyoto Mechanisms: key issues for policymakers for CoP-6; international environmental agreements" (2001) 1 Politics, Law and Economics 187–218.
83. ^Haites, E and Yamin, F, "The clean development mechanism:proposals for its operation and governance" (2000) 10 Global Environmental Change 27–45.
84. ^{{Cite web|date=March 2009|title=Global Carbon Mechanisms: Emerging lessons and implications (CTC748)|url=http://www.carbontrust.com/resources/reports/advice/global-carbon-mechanisms|publisher=Carbon Trust|accessdate=2010-03-31}}
85. ^{{cite web |url=http://greenhousegas.nsw.gov.au/ |title=The Greenhouse Gas Reduction Scheme |publisher=Greenhouse Gas Reduction Scheme Administrator |location=NSW |date=2010-01-04 |accessdate=2010-01-16 }}
86. ^{{Cite journal |first = Rob |last = Passey |first2 = Iain |last2 = MacGill |first3 = Hugh |last3 = Outhred |title = The NSW Greenhouse Gas Reduction Scheme: An analysis of the NGAC Registry for the 2003, 2004 and 2005 Compliance Periods |url=http://www.ceem.unsw.edu.au/content/userDocs/CEEM_DP_070827_000.pdf |series = CEEM discussion paper DP_070822 |year = 2007 |place = Sydney |publisher = The UNSW Centre for Energy and Environmental Markets (CEEM) |accessdate=2009-11-03 }}
87. ^{{cite web|url=http://www.abc.net.au/news/2011-06-07/abbott-defends-carbon-tax-interview/2749496|title=Abbott defends carbon tax interview|work=ABC News|accessdate=25 September 2015}}
88. ^"Julia Gillard's carbon price promise",
The Australian, 20 August 2010.
89. ^{{cite news |url=http://www.abc.net.au/news/stories/2011/02/24/3147523.htm |last=Leslie |first=Tim|newspaper=ABC News |date= 2011-02-24 |title=Gillard unveils Carbon Price Details}}
90. ^{{cite news|url=http://www.heraldsun.com.au/news/national/pm-gambles-on-carbon-tax-slug/story-e6frf7l6-1226011659564|title=Tony Abbott calls for election on carbon tax | newspaper=Herald Sun|last=Hudson |first=Phillip|date=2011-02-26|accessdate=2011-05-05 }}
91. ^{{cite web|url=http://www.heraldsun.com.au/news/more-news/carbon-tax-bills-pass-lower-house-of-federal-parliament/story-fn7x8me2-1226164570957|title=Carbon tax bills pass lower house of federal Parliament|first=Matt|last=Johnston|publisher=Herald Sun|date=October 12, 2011|accessdate=October 12, 2011}}
92. ^{{cite news|url=http://www.smh.com.au/business/carbon-tax-gets-green-light-in-senate-20111108-1n4rp.html |title=Carbon tax gets green light in Senate|work=Sydney Morning Herald|author=AAP with Reuters|date=2011-11-08}}
93. ^{{cite news |url=http://news.smh.com.au/breaking-news-national/opposition-vows-to-repeal-carbon-tax-20111002-1l3dl.html |newspaper=Sydney Morning Herald |date=2011-10-02 |title=Opposition vows to repeal carbon tax}}
94. ^"Abbott Government's first actions: trash climate change education, carbon pricing",
Indymedia Australia, 20 September 2013. Accessed 8 November 2013.
95. ^{{cite web|url=http://www.abc.net.au/news/2014-07-17/carbon-tax-repealed-by-senate/5604246|title=Carbon tax scrapped: PM Tony Abbott sees key election promise fulfilled after Senate votes for repeal|work=ABC News|accessdate=25 September 2015}}
96. ^{{cite web |url = http://www.beehive.govt.nz/release/historic+climate+change+legislation+passes |title = Historic climate change legislation passes |last = Parker |first = David |authorlink = David Parker (New Zealand politician) |date = 10 September 2008 |publisher = New Zealand Government Media Release |accessdate = 10 September 2008 |deadurl = yes |archiveurl = https://web.archive.org/web/20080926113104/http://www.beehive.govt.nz/release/historic+climate+change+legislation+passes |archivedate = 26 September 2008 |df =}}
97. ^{{cite web|url=http://www.legislation.govt.nz/act/public/2008/0085/latest/DLM1130932.html|title=Climate Change Response (Emissions Trading) Amendment Act 2008 No 85|publisher=Parliamentary Counsel Office|work=www.legislation.govt.nz|date=25 September 2008 |accessdate=25 January 2010 }}
98. ^{{cite web |url=http://beehive.govt.nz/release/balanced+new+law+important+step+climate+change|title=Balanced new law important step on climate change|publisher= New Zealand Government Press Release|author=Hon Nick Smith|authorlink=Nick Smith (New Zealand politician) |date=25 November 2009 |accessdate=14 June 2010 }}
99. ^{{cite press release|url= http://beehive.govt.nz/release/ets-amendment-bill-passes-third-reading|title= ETS Amendment Bill passes third reading|publisher= New Zealand Government |date=9 November 2012|accessdate=12 November 2012}}
100. ^{{cite web|url= http://www.mfe.govt.nz/publications/climate/greenhouse-gas-inventory-2012-snapshot/index.html|title= New Zealand's Greenhouse Gas Inventory 1990–2010 and Net Position Snapshot |publisher= Ministry for the Environment|date=October 2012|accessdate= 10 November 2012}}
101. ^{{Cite web|date= April 2010|title= New Zealand's Greenhouse Gas Inventory 1990–2008|url= http://www.mfe.govt.nz/publications/climate/greenhouse-gas-inventory-2010/index.html|work = ME 1009|publisher= Ministry for the Environment|accessdate=22 May 2010|issn= 1179-223X}}
102. ^{{cite web | title =How will the changes impact on forestry? | work = Questions and answers about amendments to the New Zealand Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS) | publisher = Ministry for the Environment | date = 14 January 2010 | url=http://www.climatechange.govt.nz/emissions-trading-scheme/questions-and-answers-amendment-act.html#forestry |accessdate=16 May 2010 }}
103. ^{{cite web|url=http://www.climatechange.govt.nz/emissions-trading-scheme/participating/waste/|title=Waste - New Zealand Climate change information|publisher=Ministry for the Environment|date=15 July 2011|accessdate=26 July 2011 }}
104. ^{{Cite web | title = Summary of the proposed changes to the NZ ETS | work = Emissions trading bulletin No 11 | publisher = Ministry for the Environment | date = September 2009 | url = http://www.mfe.govt.nz/publications/climate/emissions-trading-bulletin-11/index.html#summary | accessdate =15 May 2010}}
105. ^{{cite web|url=https://icapcarbonaction.com/images/StatusReport2015/ICAP_Report_2015_02_10_online_version.pdf|title=Emissions Trading Worldwide ICAP Status Report 2015|publisher=ICAP|date= 10 February 2015|accessdate=16 March 2015 }}
106. ^{{cite web|url=http://www.climatechange.govt.nz/emissions-trading-scheme/about/emission-units.html|title=New Zealand Units (NZUs)|work=Climate change information New Zealand |publisher=Ministry for the Environment, NZ Government (www.climatechange.govt.nz)|date=18 June 2010|accessdate=13 August 2010|quote=In the short term, the Government is unlikely to sell emission units because the Kyoto units allocated to New Zealand will be needed to support New Zealand's international obligations, as well as allocation to eligible sectors under the emissions trading scheme. }}
107. ^{{cite web|url=http://www.climatechange.govt.nz/emissions-trading-scheme/questions-and-answers-amendment-act.html#allocationwho|title=Who will get a free allocation of emission units?|work=Questions and answers about the emissions trading scheme|publisher=Ministry for the Environment, NZ Government|accessdate= 15 May 2010 |date= 14 January 2010}}
108. ^{{cite web|url=http://www.mfe.govt.nz/publications/climate/emissions-trading-bulletin-11/index.html#agriculture|title=Agriculture|work=Summary of the proposed changes to the NZ ETS - Emissions Trading Bulletin 11|publisher=Ministry for the Environment|accessdate=16 May 2010|date=September 2009 }}
109. ^{{cite web | title = Industrial allocation update | work = Emissions trading bulletin No 12, INFO 441 | publisher = Ministry for the Environment, NZ | date = September 2009 | url = http://www.mfe.govt.nz/publications/climate/emissions-trading-bulletin-12/index.html | accessdate =8 August 2010 | quote=The Bill changes the allocation provisions of the existing CCRA from allocating a fixed pool of emissions to an uncapped approach to allocation. There is no longer an explicit limit on the number of New Zealand units (NZUs) that can be allocated to the industrial sector.}}
110. ^{{cite web |title = How will free allocation of emission units to the industrial sector work now? |work = Questions and answers about amendments to the New Zealand Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS) |publisher = Ministry for the Environment |date = 14 January 2010 |url = http://www.climatechange.govt.nz/emissions-trading-scheme/building/policy-and-legislation/faq-amendment-act.html |accessdate = 16 May 2010}}
111. ^{{cite book|last = Bertram | first = Geoff|last2 = Terry |first2 = Simon|title = The Carbon Challenge: New Zealand's Emissions Trading Scheme|url= https://books.google.com/books?id=xUa6Ohd6SaIC |quote=The New Zealand ETS does not fit this model because there is no cap and therefore no certainty as to the volume of emissions with which the national economy must operate|publisher = Bridget Williams Books, Wellington |year = 2010|isbn = 978-1-877242-46-5 }}
112. ^{{cite press release |url=http://www.scoop.co.nz/stories/PO0910/S00231.htm |title=New bill ‘weakens ETS’ says Environment Commissioner|publisher=Parliamentary Commissioner for the Environment |date=15 October 2009 |accessdate=15 October 2009 |quote=The allocation of free carbon credits to industrial processes is extremely generous and removes the carbon price signal where New Zealand needs one the most}}
113. ^{{cite press release |url=http://www.scoop.co.nz/stories/PO0909/S00153.htm |title=Revised ETS an insult to New Zealanders |date=14 September 2009 |publisher=Greenpeace New Zealand |accessdate=12 October 2009 |quote=We now have on the table a pathetic ETS which won’t actually do anything to reduce emissions }}
114. ^{{cite web|url=http://www.climatechange.govt.nz/emissions-trading-scheme/ets-review-2011/statement-for-consultation.html|title=Issues statement for public consultation|work=NZ ETS Review 2011|publisher=Ministry for the Environment|date=21 April 2011|accessdate=4 November 2011}}
115. ^{{Cite journal|date=October 2007|author=Jones, B.|title= Appendix 1.2 Climate Change: Economic Impact and Policy Responses|page=64|series= World Economic and Financial Surveys, World Economic Outlook, Globalization and Inequality|publisher=IMF|url=http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2007/02/|accessdate=2010-04-26|display-authors=etal}}
116. ^Climate Change: The European Union's Emissions Trading System (EU ETS) {{webarchive |url=https://web.archive.org/web/20060830203554/http://www.opencrs.com/document/RL33581 |date=August 30, 2006 }}
117. ^{{cite news|url=http://www.washtimes.com/business/20060731-011601-7934r.htm|title=Britain, California to join forces on global warming|newspaper=The Washington Times|date=2006-07-31|accessdate=2009-11-03}}
118. ^Wagner, M. [https://www.leuphana.de/fileadmin/user_upload/Forschungseinrichtungen/csm/files/Arbeitsberichte_etc/47-4downloadversion.pdf
Firms, the Framework Convention on Climate Change & the EU Emissions Trading System]. Lüneburg: Centre for Sustainability Management 2004, p. 12.
119. ^[https://ec.europa.eu/clima/sites/clima/files/factsheet_ets_en.pdf "The EU Emissions Trading System (EU ETS)"]
120. ^{{Cite book|date=December 2008|chapter=Chapter 4: Carbon markets and carbon price |title=Building a low-carbon economy – The UK's contribution to tackling climate change|pages=140–149|chapter-url=http://www.theccc.org.uk/reports/building-a-low-carbon-economy|publisher=Committee on Climate Change|accessdate=2010-04-26}}
121. ^{{Cite web|date=3 August 2009|title=Climate Policy and Industrial Competitiveness: Ten Insights from Europe on the EU Emissions Trading System|page=11|publisher=Climate Strategies|author=Grubb, M.|accessdate=2017-04-25|url=http://climatestrategies.org/wp-content/uploads/2009/08/climate-strategies-gmf-paper-3aug09.pdf|display-authors=etal}}
122. ^Kanen, J.L.M. "Carbon Trading & Prcing". Fulton Publishing (December 2006), pp. 68–69.
123. ^{{cite web|year=2007|title=EU action against climate change|url=http://ec.europa.eu/environment/pdfs/2007/pub-2007-015-en.pdf|page=24|publisher=European Commission|accessdate=2017-04-25}}
124. ^{{cite web|year=2007|author=Norwegian Ministry of the Environment|title=The Norwegian Government accepts to include the EU Emissions Trading Directive in the EEA agreement|url=http://www.regjeringen.no/en/dep/md/press-centre/Press-releases/2006/Norway-accept-EU-Emissions-Trading-Directive.html?id=419857|pages=24|publisher=European Commission|accessdate=2010-08-03}}
125. ^{{cite web|year=2010 |title=Economic Survey of Norway 2010: Sustainable development: climate change and fisheries policies |url=http://www.oecd.org/norway/economicsurveyofnorway2010sustainabledevelopmentclimatechangeandfisheriespolicies.htm |publisher=Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development |accessdate=2017-04-25}}
126. ^{{cite web|title=EU greenhouse gas emissions and targets|url=http://ec.europa.eu/clima/policies/g-gas/index_en.htm|publisher=European Commission|accessdate=23 October 2014}}
127. ^{{cite web |url=http://artcraftjapan.wordpress.com/2010/07/16/tokyo-metropolitan-government-leads-japan-launches-own-ghg-emissions-cap-and-trade-program/ |title=Tokyo Metropolitan Government Leads Japan, Launches Own GHG Emissions Cap-and-Trade Program |publisher=Artcraft Japan |date=16 July 2010 |accessdate=5 August 2010}}
128. ^China's Carbon Emission Trading, 2012.
129. ^{{cite news |url=https://www.reuters.com/article/us-climate-japan-idUSTRE61A3XG20100211 |title=Tokyo CO2 credit trading plan may become a model |agency=Reuters |date=11 February 2010 |accessdate=25 April 2017}}
130. ^{{cite news|url=https://www.theguardian.com/environment/2010/apr/08/tokyo-carbon-trading-scheme|title=Tokyo kicks off carbon trading scheme|newspaper = The Guardian|author=Business Green|date= 2010-04-08|accessdate=2010-12-29 }}
131. ^{{cite web|url=http://web.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/TOPICS/EXTURBANDEVELOPMENT/EXTUWM/0,,contentMDK:22447034~menuPK:6722836~pagePK:210058~piPK:210062~theSitePK:341511,00.html|title=Urban Environment and Climate Change - Publications|accessdate=25 September 2015}}
132. ^{{cite web |url=https://icapcarbonaction.com/images/StatusReport2015/ICAP_Report_2015_02_10_online_version.pdf|title= Emissions Trading Worldwide ICAP Status Report 2015}}
133. ^{{cite web|url=http://www.epa.gov/airmarkt/progress/arp07.html|title=Acid Rain Program 2007 Progress Report| work=Clean Air Markets - Air & Radiation|publisher=US EPA|date=January 2009|accessdate=2011-07-25 }}
134. ^{{cite journal | last1 = Carlson | first1 = Curtis | last2 = Burtraw | first2 = Dallas | last3 = Cropper | first3 = Maureen | last4 = Palmer | first4 = Karen L. | year = 2000 | title = Sulfur dioxide control by electric utilities: What are the gains from trade? | url = | journal = Journal of Political Economy | volume = 108 | issue = 6| pages = 1292–1326 | doi=10.1086/317681}}
135. ^{{cite web |url = http://www.epa.gov/crossstaterule/ |title = Cross-State Air Pollution Rule (CSAPR) |date = 2011-07-09 |accessdate = 2011-07-10 |publisher = United States Environment Protection Agency |deadurl = yes |archiveurl = https://web.archive.org/web/20110711010737/http://www.epa.gov/crossstaterule/ |archivedate = 2011-07-11 |df =}}
136. ^[https://www.epa.gov/airmarkets/nox-budget-trading-program "NOx Budget Trading Program"], Environmental Protection Agency. Retrieved 25 April 2017.]
137. ^[https://www.epa.gov/sites/production/files/2015-08/documents/ozone_fact_sheet.pdf "Ozone Fact Sheet"], Environmental Protection Agency. Retrieved 25 April 2017.
138. ^{{cite web|title=Cap and Trade|url=http://www.epa.gov/captrade/|publisher=United States Environmental Protection Agency|accessdate=27 October 2014}}
139. ^{{Cite journal|first=Olivier|last=Deschênes|first2=Michael|last2=Greenstone|last3=Shapiro|first3= Joseph|date=2017|title=Defensive Investments and the Demand for Air Quality: Evidence from the NOx Budget Program|journal=American Economic Review|volume=107|issue=10|pages=2958–2989|doi=10.1257/aer.20131002|issn=0002-8282}}
140. ^{{Cite web|url=https://www.epa.gov/indoor-air-quality-iaq/volatile-organic-compounds-impact-indoor-air-quality|title=Volatile Organic Compounds' Impact on Indoor Air Quality {{!}} US EPA|last=EPA,OAR,ORIA,IED|first=US|website=US EPA|access-date=2017-11-30}}
141. ^{{Cite web|url=https://www.health.ny.gov/environmental/indoors/voc.htm|title=Volatile Organic Compounds (VOCs) in Commonly Used Products|website=www.health.ny.gov|access-date=2017-11-30}}
142. ^{{Cite web|url=https://water.usgs.gov/nawqa/vocs/national_assessment/report/chapter1.html|title=Chapter 1 - Major Findings and Conclusions|last=Synthesis|first=NAWQA VOC National|website=water.usgs.gov|access-date=2017-11-30}}
143. ^{{Cite web|url=http://www.health.state.mn.us/divs/eh/indoorair/voc/|title=Volatile Organic Compounds (VOCs) in Your Home - EH: Minnesota Department of Health|website=www.health.state.mn.us|access-date=2017-11-30}}
144. ^{{cite web | url = http://www.renewableenergyworld.com/rea/news/article/2009/03/presidents-budget-draws-clean-energy-funds-from-climate-measure | title = President's Budget Draws Clean Energy Funds from Climate Measure |publisher=Renewable Energy World |accessdate=2009-04-03}}
145. ^{{cite web|url=http://energycommerce.house.gov/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=1633&catid=155&Itemid=55 |title=The American Clean Energy and Security Act (H.R. 2454) |publisher=Energycommerce.house.gov |date=2009-06-01 |accessdate=2010-06-14}}
146. ^{{cite book |last1=Dryzek |first1=John S. |authorlink1=John Dryzek |first2=Richard B. |last2=Norgaard |authorlink2=Richard Norgaard |first3=David |last3=Schlosberg |title=The Oxford Handbook of Climate Change and Society |publisher=Oxford University Press |date=2011 |isbn=9780199683420 |page=154}}
147. ^{{cite news |url=http://www.newyorker.com/magazine/2010/08/30/covert-operations |authorlink=Jane Mayer |first=Jane |last=Mayer |title=Covert Operations: The billionaire brothers who are waging a war against Obama |journal=The New Yorker |date=30 August 2010 |accessdate=20 March 2015}}
148. ^{{cite news | url = http://www.newyorker.com/reporting/2010/10/11/101011fa_fact_lizza | title = As the World Burns: How the Senate and the White House missed their best chance to deal with climate change | journal=The New Yorker | date=11 October 2010 | first=Ryan | last=Lizza}}
149. ^{{cite journal | author=Turin, Dustin R. | title=The Challenges of Climate Change Policy: Explaining the Failure of Cap and Trade in the United States With a Multiple-Streams Framework | journal=Student Pulse | volume=4 | issue=6 | year=2012 |url=http://www.studentpulse.com/articles/656/3/the-challenges-of-climate-change-policy-explaining-the-failure-of-cap-and-trade-in-the-united-states-with-a-multiple-streams-framework}}
150. ^Memorandum of Understanding - Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative
151. ^{{cite web |url=http://www.carbon-financeonline.com/index.cfm?section=features&id=11092&action=view&return=home |title=Beyond the Kyoto six |work=Carbon Finance |publisher=Fulton Publishing |first=Kristian |last=Brüning |first2=Jeff |last2=Cohen |date=2008-03-07 |accessdate=2011-07-26 |deadurl=yes |archiveurl=https://web.archive.org/web/20110727011403/https://www.carbon-financeonline.com/index.cfm?section=features&id=11092&action=view&return=home |archivedate=2011-07-27 |df=}}
152. ^{{cite news|last=Barringer|first=Felicity|title=California Law to Curb Greenhouse Gases Faces a Legal Hurdle|url=https://www.nytimes.com/2011/02/05/science/earth/05emit.html|accessdate=9 February 2011|newspaper=The New York Times|date=4 February 2011}}
153. ^{{cite news|last=Buchanan|first=Wyatt|title=Calif. cap-trade plan dealt blow by S.F. judge|url=http://articles.sfgate.com/2011-02-04/news/27100791_1_air-board-ab32-emissions-plan|accessdate=9 February 2011|newspaper=San Francisco Chronicle|date=4 February 2011|deadurl=yes|archiveurl=https://web.archive.org/web/20110208141038/http://articles.sfgate.com/2011-02-04/news/27100791_1_air-board-ab32-emissions-plan|archivedate=8 February 2011}}
154. ^California Cap and Trade, Center for Climate and Energy Solutions, January 2014.
155. ^Summary of California's Cap and Trade Program, Center for Climate and Energy Solutions.
156. ^{{Cite web|url=https://www.tceq.texas.gov/airquality/banking/hrvoc_ept_prog.html|title=Highly Reactive Volatile Organic Compound Emissions Cap and Trade Program|website=TCEQ|access-date=2017-11-30}}
157. ^Western Climate Initiative.
158. ^"California, New Mexico and 3 Canadian provinces outline regional cap-and-trade program",
Los Angeles Times, 28 July 2010.
159. ^"Six US states leave the Western Climate Initiative" (18 November 2011). S&P Global Platts. Retrieved 2016-11-26.
160. ^"6 States Pull Out of Western Climate Initiative" (22 November 2011).
SustainableBusiness.com News. Retrieved 2016-11-26.
161. ^{{cite web|url=http://www.epa.state.il.us/air/erms/|title=Emissions Reduction Market System What Is ERMS?|year=2007|publisher=Illinois EPA}}
162. ^{{cite web|url=https://icapcarbonaction.com/images/StatusReport2015/ICAP_Report_2015_02_10_online_version.pdf|title= Emissions Trading Worldwide ICAP Status Report 2015}}
163. ^{{Cite web|url=https://www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/content/article/2006/03/28/AR2006032801565.html|title=China Considers Tradable Pollution-Rights Permits|last=Bartson|first=Andrew|date=March 29, 2006|website=The Wall Street Journal|access-date=}}
164. ^{{Cite journal|last=|first=|date=2014|title=Can China's Industrial SO2 Emissions Trading Pilot Scheme Reduce Pollution Abatement Costs?|url=https://pdfs.semanticscholar.org/16cc/3e7697af62c650bc240e927f9cfe892836ae.pdf|journal=Sustainability|volume=|pages=|via=}}
165. ^{{Cite news|url=https://www.under2coalition.org/what-we-do/news-and-blogs/china-considers-national-pollution-permit-trading|title=China considers national pollution permit trading|date=2014-01-14|work=Under2 Coalition|access-date=2018-09-08}}
166. ^{{Cite web|url=https://www.ictsd.org/bridges-news/bridges/news/china-looks-towards-next-steps-for-implementing-national-carbon-market|title=China Looks Towards Next Steps For Implementing National Carbon Market|last=|first=|date=January 18, 2018|website=ICTSD|access-date=}}
167. ^{{cite web|url=http://www.climatechangenews.com/2014/09/01/china-could-launch-national-carbon-market-in-2016/|title=China could launch national carbon market in 2016|website=CLIMATE HOME}}
168. ^{{Cite journal|url = http://nbr.org/publications/element.aspx?id=790|title = China's Energy Policymaking Processes and Their Consequences|last = Andrews-Speed|first = Philip|date = November 2014|journal = The National Bureau of Asian Research Energy Security Report|doi = |pmid = |access-date = December 24, 2014}}
169. ^{{cite web|url=https://www.reuters.com/article/2011/07/11/us-carbon-schemes-idUSTRE76A2GJ20110711|title=Factbox: Carbon trading schemes around the world|work=Reuters|accessdate=25 September 2015}}
170. ^{{Cite web|url=https://www.ft.com/content/cd549b9a-e088-11e7-a8a4-0a1e63a52f9c|title=China moves towards launch of carbon trading scheme|last=Feng|first=Emily|date=December 19, 2017|website=Financial Times|access-date=}}
171. ^{{Cite web|url=https://unfccc.int/news/china-to-launch-world-s-largest-emissions-trading-system|title=China to Launch World's Largest Emissions Trading System|last=|first=|date=December 19, 2017|website=UNFCCC|access-date=}}
172. ^{{cite web|url=http://www.rtcc.org/2014/01/08/global-carbon-market-to-rise-15-in-value-in-2014-bloomberg-analysts/|title=Global carbon market to rise 15% in value in 2014|work=Climate Home|accessdate=25 September 2015}}
173. ^{{cite web |url=https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/bitstream/handle/10986/13409/37579.pdf |title=State and Trends of the Carbon Market |year=2006 |publisher=World Bank |accessdate=2017-04-25}}
174. ^{{cite web |url=https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/bitstream/handle/10986/13411/332360CarbonMarketStudy2005.pdf |title=State and Trends of the Carbon Market |year=2005 |publisher=World Bank |accessdate=2017-04-25}}
175. ^{{cite web|url=http://www.redd-monitor.org/2014/01/09/global-carbon-markets-have-shrunk-in-value-by-60-since-2011/|title=Global carbon markets have shrunk in value by 60% since 2011|work=REDD-Monitor|accessdate=25 September 2015}}
176. ^{{cite web |url=https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/bitstream/handle/10986/13405/44607.pdf |title=State and Trends of the Carbon Market |year=2008 |publisher=World Bank |accessdate=2017-04-25}}
177. ^{{cite web|title=Allowance Trading Basic|url=http://www.epa.gov/airmarkets/trading/basics.html|publisher=US Environmental Protection Agency|accessdate=26 Oct 2014}}
178. ^{{cite book |last=Stavins |first= Robert N.|first2= Judson |last2=Jaffe |year=2008 |title=Linkage of Tradable Permit Systems in International Climate Policy Architecture |publisher=Harvard Project on International Climate Agreements |url=http://belfercenter.ksg.harvard.edu/publication/18580/}}
179. ^International Carbon Action Partnership.
180. ^{{cite web |title=The Cap and Trade Pollution Solution |url=http://www.power-technology.com/features/feature1520/ |first=Drew |last=Turney |publisher=Net Resources International |accessdate=21 May 2012}}
181. ^
The carbon market Fiona Harvey, FT April 27, 2007
182. ^{{cite web|url=http://www.weforum.org/pdf/g8_climatechange.pdf |title=Statement of G8 Climate Change Roundtable |publisher=World Economic Forum |date=9 June 2005 |deadurl=yes |archiveurl=https://web.archive.org/web/20130508123035/http://www.weforum.org/pdf/g8_climatechange.pdf |archivedate=2013-05-08 }}
183. ^List of climate leaders EPA December 12
184. ^{{Cite book |chapter-url=http://www.berr.gov.uk/files/file39578.pdf |title=Meeting the Energy Challenge |date=May 2007 |chapter=UK Position on the EU Emissions Trading Scheme |publisher=UK Department of Trade and Industry |accessdate=2017-04-25 |deadurl=bot: unknown |archiveurl=http://webarchive.nationalarchives.gov.uk/20090609003228/http://www.berr.gov.uk/files/file39578.pdf |archivedate=2009-06-09 }}
185. ^{{cite news |url=http://www.canada.com/calgaryherald/news/calgarybusiness/story.html?id=e8aecbbb-16c6-412d-8054-7e64e2b176ef |title=Exxon supports carbon tax |newspaper=Calgary Herald News |date=2009-01-09 |deadurl=yes |archiveurl=https://web.archive.org/web/20090122051143/http://www.canada.com/calgaryherald/news/calgarybusiness/story.html?id=e8aecbbb-16c6-412d-8054-7e64e2b176ef |archivedate=2009-01-22 }}
186. ^{{cite web |title=What You Need to Know About Emissions Trading |publisher= International Air Transport Association |accessdate=2009-09-26 |url= http://www.iata.org/NR/rdonlyres/95D34D98-7906-4A23-8884-1FA561709037/53257/EmissionsTrading.pdf |archiveurl = https://web.archive.org/web/20070303092647/http://www.iata.org/NR/rdonlyres/95D34D98-7906-4A23-8884-1FA561709037/53257/EmissionsTrading.pdf |archivedate = March 3, 2007}}
187. ^{{cite web|title=MRV&Enforcement|url=https://icapcarbonaction.com/ets-topics/mvr-and-enforcement|publisher=International Carbon Action Partnership (ICAP)|accessdate=26 Oct 2014}}
188. ^{{cite book|last=Tiwari|first=Gopal Nath|title=Building integrated photovoltaic thermal systems : for sustainable developments|year=2010|publisher=Royal Society of Chemistry|location=Cambridge|isbn=978-1-84973-090-7|author2=Agrawal, Basant}}
189. ^{{cite journal |url=http://www.iisd.ca/journal/ott.html |first=Hermann E. |last=Ott |title=Emissions Trading in the Kyoto Protocol, Finished and Unfinished Business |date=1998-10-26 |journal=Linkages Journal |volume=3 |series=4 }}
190. ^{{cite journal|year=2007|author=Nordhaus, W.D.|title=To Tax of Not to Tax: Alternative Approaches to Slowing Global Warming|journal=Review of Environmental Economics and Policy|volume=1|issue=1|page=27|url=http://www.oxfordjournals.org/our_journals/reep/press_releases/freepdf/issue1.pdf|accessdate=2010-04-28|doi=10.1093/reep/rem008}}
191. ^{{cite journal|year=2007|author1=Ellerman, A.D. |author2=B.K. Buchner|title=The European Union Emissions Trading Scheme: Origins, Allocation, and Early Results|journal=Review of Environmental Economics and Policy|volume=1|issue=1|page=71|url=http://www.oxfordjournals.org/our_journals/reep/press_releases/freepdf/issue1.pdf|accessdate=2010-04-28|doi=10.1093/reep/rem003 }}
192. ^{{cite journal|year=2007|author=Kruger, J.|title=Decentralization in the EU Emissions Trading Scheme and Lessons for Global Policy|journal=Review of Environmental Economics and Policy|volume=1|issue=1|pages=130–131|url=http://www.oxfordjournals.org/our_journals/reep/press_releases/freepdf/issue1.pdf|accessdate=2010-04-28|display-authors=etal|doi=10.1093/reep/rem009}}
193. ^{{Cite book|date=6 June 2009|title=The Economics of Climate Change Mitigation: How to Build the Necessary Global Action in a Cost-Effective Manner|series=Economics Department Working Papers No. 701|author=Burniaux, J-M.|url=http://appli1.oecd.org/olis/2009doc.nsf/linkto/eco-wkp%282009%2942|publisher=OECD|accessdate=2010-04-24|display-authors=etal|page=56}}
194. ^{{cite journal|doi=10.2307/1911364|jstor=1911364|title=Subgame Perfect Implementation|journal=Econometrica|volume=56|issue=5|pages=1191|year=1988|last1=Moore|first1=John|last2=Repullo|first2=Rafael}}
195. ^{{cite journal|doi=10.1016/j.econlet.2008.07.003|title=A complete implementation of the efficient allocation of pollution|journal=Economics Letters|volume=101|issue=2|pages=142|year=2008|last1=Kahana|first1=Nava|last2=Mealem|first2=Yosef|last3=Nitzan|first3=Shmuel}}
196. ^{{cite journal|doi=10.1257/00028280260344614|title=Implementing the Efficient Allocation of Pollution|journal=American Economic Review|volume=92|issue=4|pages=1070|year=2002|last1=Duggan|first1=John|last2=Roberts|first2=Joanne}}
197. ^{{Cite journal |last=Lohmann |first=Larry |title=A licence to carry on polluting? |journal=New Scientist |volume=2580 |date=2006-12-05 |url=https://www.newscientist.com/article/mg19225805.900-a-licence-to-carry-on-polluting.html |archiveurl=http://www.thecornerhouse.org.uk/resource/carry-polluting |archivedate=2006-12-05 |accessdate=2010-07-17}}
198. ^{{cite web|last=Lohmann|first=Larry|url=http://www.thecornerhouse.org.uk/summary.shtml?x=544238|title=Ways forward (The Corner House)|publisher=The Corner House|year=2006b|accessdate=2009-04-03}}
199. ^{{Cite web|url=http://www.carbontradewatch.org/publications/carbon-trading-how-it-works-and-why-it-fails.html|date=November 2009|author=Carbon Trade Watch|title=Carbon Trading – How it works and why it fails|publisher=Dag Hammarskjöld Foundation|accessdate=2010-08-04}}
200. ^{{cite web |url=http://www.storyofstuff.com/capandtrade/capandtrade.php |title=The Story of Cap and Trade |author=Annie Leonard |year=2009 |publisher=The Story of Stuff Project |accessdate=2010-10-31 |deadurl=yes |archiveurl=https://web.archive.org/web/20101103024644/http://storyofstuff.com/capandtrade/capandtrade.php |archivedate=2010-11-03 }}
201. ^{{Cite web|url=http://www.newint.org/features/2006/07/01/carbon-cycle/|title=10 things you should know about tree 'offsets'|author=Kill, J.|date=July 2006|publisher=New Internationalist|accessdate=2010-04-28}}
202. ^{{cite journal |year = 2006 |title = Regulating by prices, quantities or both: an update and an overview |author = Hepburn, C. |journal = Oxford Review of Economic Policy |volume = 22 |issue = 2 |doi = 10.1093/oxrep/grj014 |url = http://www.economics.ox.ac.uk/members/cameron.hepburn/Hepburn%20(2006,%20Oxrep)%20Regulation%20by%20P%20or%20Q.pdf |pages = 236–239 |accessdate = 30 August 2009 |deadurl = yes |archiveurl = https://web.archive.org/web/20090114050347/http://www.economics.ox.ac.uk/members/cameron.hepburn/Hepburn%20%282006%2C%20Oxrep%29%20Regulation%20by%20P%20or%20Q.pdf |archivedate = 14 January 2009 |df =}}
203. ^{{cite book|year=2001|chapter=6. Policies, Measures, and Instruments|title=Climate Change 2001: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change|editor=B. Metz|publisher=IPCC|author=Bashmakov, I.|chapter-url=http://www.grida.no/climate/ipcc_tar/wg3/237.htm|accessdate=2010-04-26|display-authors=etal|display-editors=etal}}
204. ^{{Cite web|url=http://www.imf.org/external/np/pp/eng/2008/022208.pdf|date=March 2008|title=Fiscal Implications of Climate Change|pages=25–26|publisher=International Monetary Fund|accessdate=2010-04-26}}
205. ^{{cite news|url=http://economist.com/opinion/displaystory.cfm?story_id=E1_RVJTRQV|title=Climate change; The greening of America|newspaper=The Economist|date=2007-01-25|accessdate=2009-04-03}}
206. ^{{cite book|year=1996|author=Fisher, B.S.|chapter=An Economic Assessment of Policy Instruments for Combating Climate Change|title=Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change|page=417|editor=J.P. Bruce|publisher=IPCC|chapter-url=http://www.ipcc.ch/ipccreports/sar/wg_III/ipcc_sar_wg_III_full_report.pdf|isbn=978-0-521-56854-8|doi=10.2277/0521568544|display-authors=etal|display-editors=etal}}
207. ^{{Cite web|date=19 June 2008|author=Cambridge Centre for Climate Change Mitigation Research|title=The Revision of the EU's Emissions Trading System|url=https://publications.parliament.uk/pa/ld200708/ldselect/ldeucom/197/8100802.htm|publisher=UK Parliament|accessdate=2010-04-28}}
208. ^{{cite web|last=Stone|first=Chad|last2=Shaw|first2=Hannah|title=Senate can strengthen climate legislation by reducing corporate welfare and boosting true consumer relief|url=http://www.cbpp.org/files/7-10-09climate.pdf|publisher=Centre for Budget and Policy Priorities|date=2009-07-10|accessdate=2010-01-27 }}
209. ^[https://icapcarbonaction.com/index.php?option=com_attach&task=download&id=241 "Linking Emissions Trading Systems: A Summary of Current Research"], ICAP 2015.
210. ^Burtraw, D., Palmer, K. L., Munnings, C., Weber, P., & Woerman, M., 2013: Linking by Degrees: Incremental Alignment of Cap-and-Trade Markets. SSRN Electronic Journal. doi:10.2139/ssrn.2249955
211. ^Flachsland, C., Marschinski, R., & Edenhofer, O., 2009: To link or not to link: benefits and disadvantages of linking cap-and-trade systems. Climate Policy, 9(4), 358–372. doi:10.3763/cpol.2009.0626
212. ^Ranson, M., & Stavins, R., 2013: Linkage of Greenhouse Gas Emissions Trading Systems - Learning from Experience. Discussion Paper Resources For The Future, No. 42
213. ^The House of Commons Energy and Climate Committee, 2015: Linking emissions trading systems. London.
214. ^"Quebec, Ontario, Manitoba sign agreement to link cap-and-trade systems", CBC News, 7 December 2015.
215. ^{{cite web|title=California-Ontario-Québec Agreement on the Harmonization and Integration of their Cap-and-Trade Programs|url=https://www.arb.ca.gov/cc/capandtrade/linkage/2017_linkage_agreement_ca-qc-on.pdf|website=California Air Resources Board|publisher=Government of California|accessdate=14 November 2017}}
216. ^{{cite web|url=https://icapcarbonaction.com/|title=International Carbon Action Partnership (ICAP)|accessdate=25 September 2015}}

Further reading

  • {{Cite web

|year=2015
|author1=Constanze Haug |author2=Michel Frerk |author3=Marissa Santikarn |title=Towards a global price on carbon: Pathways for linking carbon pricing instruments
|publisher=adelphi
|url=http://www.adelphi.de/en/publications/dok/43509.php?pid=2002
|accessdate=11 June 2015}}
  • {{Cite web

|year=2015
|author=Camille Serre
|title=Emissions Trading Worldwide: International Carbon Action Partnership (ICAP) Status Report 2015
|publisher=International Carbon Action Partnership, ICAP
|url=https://icapcarbonaction.com/status-report-2015
|accessdate=14 March 2015|display-authors=etal}}
  • {{cite journal

|year=2012
|author1=Yujie Lu |author2=Qingbin Cui |author3=Xinyuan Zhu |title=Effectiveness and equity implications of carbon policies in the United States construction industry
|journal=Building and Environment
|volume=49
|pages=259–269
|publisher=Elsevier Ltd.
|doi=10.1016/j.buildenv.2011.10.002}}
  • {{cite web

|year=2010
|author=DuPont, Kyle
|title=Cities and Climate Change Mitigation: Case Study on Tokyo's Emissions Trading System
|publisher=World Bank
|url=http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTURBANDEVELOPMENT/Resources/336387-1226422021646/Tokyo_ETS_Padeco.pdf
|accessdate=22 November 2012}}
  • {{cite journal

|year=2009
|author1=Lin Feng |author2=Jason Buhi |title=Emissions Trading Across China: Incorporating Hong Kong and Macau into an Urgently Needed Air Pollution Control Regime Under 'One Country, Two Systems'
|ssrn=1441395
|publisher=Florida State University Journal of Transnational Law & Policy, Vol. 19, 2009}}
  • {{Cite web

|date=1 November 2009
|author1=Gilbertson, T. |author2=O. Reyes
|title=Carbon Trading: how it works and why it fails
|url=http://www.carbontradewatch.org/publications/carbon-trading-how-it-works-and-why-it-fails.html
|publisher=Dag Hammarskjöld Foundation
|accessdate=2010-05-14}}
  • {{Cite web

|date=22 November 2007
|author1=Reinaud, J. |author2=C. Philibert
|title=Emissions trading: trends and prospects
|page=43
|url=http://www.iea.org/publications/free_new_Desc.asp?PUBS_ID=2001
|publisher=International Energy Agency
|accessdate=2010-05-12}}
  • {{Cite web

|year=2005
|title=Act Locally, Trade Globally- Emissions Trading for Climate Policy
|page=236
|url=http://www.iea.org/publications/free_new_Desc.asp?PUBS_ID=1579
|publisher=International Energy Agency
|accessdate=2010-05-12}}
  • {{Cite web

|year=2000
|editor1-last=Chichilnisky|editor1-first=C.|editor1-link=Graciela Chichilnisky|editor2-first=G.|editor2-last=Heal
|title=Environmental Markets: Equity and Efficiency
|url=http://www.chichilnisky.com/publication.php
|publisher=Columbia University Press
|accessdate=2010-05-12}}
  • {{Cite web

|date=1 January 2000
|author1=Norregaard, J. |author2=V. Reppelin-Hill
|title=Taxes and Tradable Permits as Instruments for Controlling Pollution: Theory and Practice. Working Paper No. 00/13
|url=http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/cat/longres.cfm?sk=3411.0
|publisher=International Monetary Fund
|accessdate=2010-05-12}}
  • {{cite journal

|year=2000
|author1=Susanne Schennach |title=The Economics of Pollution Permit Banking in the Context of Title IV of the 1990 Clean Air Act Amendments
|journal=Journal of Environmental Economics and Management
|volume=40
|issue=3 |pages=189–210
|publisher=Elsevier
|doi=10.1006/jeem.1999.1122
|url=https://ideas.repec.org/a/eee/jeeman/v40y2000i3p189-210.html}}

External links

{{Library resources box
|by=no
|onlinebooks=no
|others=no
|about=yes
|label=Emissions trading }}
  • [https://web.archive.org/web/20100208161649/http://nmcep.nmt.edu/index.php/NMCEP-and-Related-News/cap-and-trade-changing-everything.html Dr. Daniel Fine of the New Mexico Center for Energy Policy on Cap and Trade]
  • [https://www.iea.org/topics/climatechange/subtopics/emissionstradingandcdm/ Emissions Trading and CDM] – International Energy Agency
  • Greenhouse Gas Emissions Trading and Project-based Mechanisms – Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development
  • US EPA's Acid Rain Program
  • Illinois Emissions Reduction Market System
  • "The Making of a Market-Minded Environmentalist", article by Fred Krupp in Strategy+Business (registration required) that articulates some of the reasoning and history behind emissions trading in California
  • International Emissions Trading Association
{{Emissions Trading schemes}}{{Global warming|state=collapsed}}{{Sustainability}}{{Natural resources}}{{DEFAULTSORT:Emissions Trading}}

5 : Articles with inconsistent citation formats|Climate change policy|Economics and climate change|Emissions trading|Environmental controversies

随便看

 

开放百科全书收录14589846条英语、德语、日语等多语种百科知识,基本涵盖了大多数领域的百科知识,是一部内容自由、开放的电子版国际百科全书。

 

Copyright © 2023 OENC.NET All Rights Reserved
京ICP备2021023879号 更新时间:2024/11/11 9:58:58