请输入您要查询的百科知识:

 

词条 Information asymmetry
释义

  1. Models

  2. Adverse selection

      Signaling   Screening 

  3. Application in research

  4. Information gathering

  5. Sources

  6. Effect of blogging

  7. Information asymmetry and artificial intelligence

  8. See also

  9. Notes

  10. References

  11. External links

In contract theory and economics, information asymmetry deals with the study of decisions in transactions where one party has more or better information than the other. This asymmetry creates an imbalance of power in transactions, which can sometimes cause the transactions to go awry, a kind of market failure in the worst case. Examples of this problem are adverse selection,[1] moral hazard, and monopolies of knowledge.[2]

Information asymmetry extends to non-economic behavior. As private firms have better information than regulators about the actions that they would take in the absence of a regulation, the effectiveness of a regulation may be undermined.[3] International relations theory has recognized that wars may be caused by asymmetric information{{sfn|Jackson and Morelli|pp=35, 40-43}} and that "Most of the great wars of the modern era resulted from leaders miscalculating their prospects for victory".{{sfn|Ikenberry|p=128}} There is asymmetric information between national leaders, wrote Jackson and Morelli, when there are differences "in what they know [i.e. believe] about each other's armaments, quality of military personnel and tactics, determination, geography, political climate, or even just about the relative probability of different outcomes" or where they have "incomplete information about the motivations of other agents".{{sfn|Jackson and Morelli|pp=40, 42}}

Information asymmetries are studied in the context of principal–agent problems where they are a major cause of misinforming and is essential in every communication process.[4] Information asymmetry is in contrast to perfect information, which is a key assumption in neo-classical economics.[5] In 2001 the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics was awarded to George Akerlof, Michael Spence, and Joseph E. Stiglitz for their "analyses of markets with asymmetric information".[6]

Models

Information asymmetry models assume that at least one party to a transaction has relevant information, whereas the other(s) do not. Some asymmetric information models can also be used in situations where at least one party can enforce, or effectively retaliate for breaches of, certain parts of an agreement, whereas the other(s) cannot.

In adverse selection models, the ignorant party lacks information while negotiating an agreed understanding of or contract to the transaction, whereas in moral hazard the ignorant party lacks information about performance of the agreed-upon transaction or lacks the ability to retaliate for a breach of the agreement. An example of adverse selection is when people who are high-risk are more likely to buy insurance because the insurance company cannot effectively discriminate against them, usually due to lack of information about the particular individual's risk but also sometimes by force of law or other constraints. An example of moral hazard is when people are more likely to behave recklessly after becoming insured, either because the insurer cannot observe this behavior or cannot effectively retaliate against it, for example by failing to renew the insurance. Mechanisms such as forcing one party to reveal its preferences by making hard choices can reveal information that can be used in subsequent iterations of a game with multiple rounds.[7]

Adverse selection

The classic paper on adverse selection is George Akerlof's "The Market for Lemons" from 1970, which brought informational issues to the forefront of economic theory.

It discusses two primary solutions to this problem, signaling and screening.[8]

Signaling

Michael Spence originally proposed the idea of signaling.[9] He proposed that in a situation with information asymmetry, it is possible for people to signal their type, thus believably transferring information to the other party and resolving the asymmetry.

This idea was originally studied in the context of matching in the job market. An employer is interested in hiring a new employee who is "skilled in learning". Of course, all prospective employees will claim to be "skilled at learning", but only they know if they really are. This is an information asymmetry.

Spence proposes, for example, that going to college can function as a credible signal of an ability to learn. Assuming that people who are skilled in learning can finish college more easily than people who are unskilled, then by finishing college the skilled people signal their skill to prospective employers. No matter how much or how little they may have learned in college or what they studied, finishing functions as a signal of their capacity for learning. However, finishing college may merely function as a signal of their ability to pay for college, it may signal the willingness of individuals to adhere to orthodox views, or it may signal a willingness to comply with authority.

Screening

Joseph E. Stiglitz pioneered the theory of screening. In this way the underinformed party can induce the other party to reveal their information. They can provide a menu of choices in such a way that the choice depends on the private information of the other party.

Examples of situations where the seller usually has better information than the buyer are numerous but include used-car salespeople, mortgage brokers and loan originators, stockbrokers and real estate agents.

Examples of situations where the buyer usually has better information than the seller include estate sales as specified in a last will and testament, life insurance, or sales of old art pieces without prior professional assessment of their value. This situation was first described by Kenneth J. Arrow in an article on health care in 1963.[10]

George Akerlof in The Market for Lemons notices that, in such a market, the average value of the commodity tends to go down, even for those of perfectly good quality. Because of information asymmetry, unscrupulous sellers can "spoof" items (like replica goods such as watches) and defraud the buyer. As a result, many people not willing to risk getting ripped off will avoid certain types of purchases, or will not spend as much for a given item. Akerlof demonstrates that it is even possible for the market to decay to the point of nonexistence.

Application in research

Since the seminal contributions of Akerlof, Spence, and Stiglitz, the pervasive effects of information asymmetry in markets have been documented and studied in numerous contexts. In particular, a substantial portion of research in the field of accounting can be framed in terms of information asymmetry, since accounting involves the transmission of an enterprise's information from those who have it to those who need it for decision-making. Likewise, financial economists apply information asymmetry in studies of differentially informed financial market participants (insiders, stock analysts, investors, etc.) or in the cost of finance for MFIs.[11] Information asymmetry has also seen some use in behavioral economics.

Information gathering

Most models in traditional contract theory assume that asymmetric information is exogenously given.[12][13] Yet, some authors have also studied contract-theoretic models in which asymmetric information arises endogenously, because agents decide whether or not to gather information. Specifically, Crémer and Khalil (1992) and Crémer, Khalil, and Rochet (1998a) study an agent’s incentives to acquire private information after a principal has offered a contract.[14][15] In a laboratory experiment, Hoppe and Schmitz (2013) have provided empirical support for the theory.[16] Several further models have been developed which study variants of this setup. For instance, when the agent has not gathered information at the outset, does it make a difference whether or not he learns the information later on, before production starts?[17] What happens if the information can be gathered already before a contract is offered?[18] What happens if the principal observes the agent’s decision to acquire information?[19] Finally, the theory has been applied in several contexts such as public-private partnerships and vertical integration.[20][21]

Sources

Information asymmetry within societies can be created and maintained in several ways. Firstly, media outlets, due to their ownership structure or political influences, may fail to disseminate certain viewpoints or engage in propaganda campaigns. Furthermore, an educational system relying on substantial tuition fees can generate information imbalances between the poor and the affluent. Imbalances can also be fortified by certain organizational and legal measures, such as document classification procedures or non-disclosure clauses. Exclusive information networks that are operational around the world further contribute to the asymmetry. Lastly, mass surveillance helps the political and industrial leaders to amass large volumes of information, which is typically not shared with the rest of the society.[22]

Effect of blogging

Blogging on financial websites provides bottom-up communication among investors, analysts, journalists, and academics, as financial blogs help prevent people in charge from withholding financial information from their company and the general public.{{Citation-needed|date=February 2018}} Compared to traditional forms of media such as newspapers and magazines, blogging provides an easy-to-access venue for information. A 2013 study by Saxton and Anker concluded that more participation on blogging sites from credible individuals reduces information asymmetry between corporate insiders, additionally reducing the risk of insider trading.[23]

Information asymmetry and artificial intelligence

Tshilidzi Marwala and Evan Hurwitz in their study of the relationship between information asymmetry and artificial intelligence observed that there is less level of information asymmetry between two artificial intelligent agents than between two human agents. Thus intelligent agents in the market make the markets more efficient. They furthermore observed that the more artificial intelligent buying and selling agents there are in the market the less is the volume of trades in the market.[24][25] This is primarily because information asymmetry of the perceptions of value of goods and services is the basis of trade.

See also

  • Artificial scarcity
  • Asymmetric competition
  • Bounded rationality
  • Inequality of bargaining power
  • Perfect information
  • Real prices and ideal prices

Notes

1. ^Charles Wilson (2008). "adverse selection," The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd Edition. Abstract.
2. ^John O. Ledyard (2008). "market failure,"  The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Ed.  Abstract.
3. ^{{cite book |last1=Fullerton |first1=Don |last2=Wolfram |first2=Catherine |title=The Design and Implementation of U.S. Climate Policy |date=13 May 2010 |publisher=University of Chicago Press |location=Chicago Illinois |isbn=9780226269146 |pages=11 |url=https://www.nber.org/chapters/c12123.pdf |accessdate=9 March 2019}}
4. ^Christozov D., Chukova S., Mateev P., Chapter 11. Informing Processes, Risks, Evaluation of the Risk of Misinforming, in [https://books.google.com/books?printsec=frontcover&id=3qtlYfQut1wC Foundations of Informing Science], ISI, 2009, pp. 323-356
5. ^https://www.nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/economic-sciences/laureates/2001/stiglitz-lecture.pdf
6. ^[https://www.nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/economic-sciences/laureates/2001/press.html "The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 2001: Information for the Public"], press release from the Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences, Nobel Foundation, nobelprize.org, October 2001, accessed November 12, 2007.
7. ^{{cite journal |title=Limited Liability and the Known Unknown |journal=Duke Law Journal |volume=68 |date=2018 |page=275 |ssrn=3121519 }}
8. ^Johannes Hörne (2008). "signalling and screening" The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. Abstract.
9. ^{{cite journal |last1=Spence |first1=Michael |title=Job Market Signaling |journal=The Quarterly Journal of Economics |date=August 1973 |volume=87 |issue=3 |pages=355–374 |doi=10.2307/1882010 |language=en |issn=0033-5533|jstor=1882010 }}
10. ^{{Cite journal |last=Arrow |first=Kenneth J. |year=1963 |title=Uncertainty and the Welfare Economics of Medical Care |periodical=American Economic Review |volume=53 |issue=5 |pages=941–973 |jstor= 1812044|doi= |publisher=American Economic Association }}
11. ^{{cite journal|last1=Garmaise, M. & G. Natividad|title=Information, the Cost of Credit, and Operational Efficiency: An Empirical Study of Microfinance|journal=Review of Financial Studies|date=2010|volume=23|issue=6|pages=2560–2590 |doi=10.1093/rfs/hhq021}}
12. ^{{Cite journal|last=Baron|first=David P.|last2=Myerson|first2=Roger B.|date=1982|title=Regulating a Monopolist with Unknown Costs|journal=Econometrica|volume=50|issue=4|pages=911–930|doi=10.2307/1912769|jstor=1912769|citeseerx=10.1.1.407.6185}}
13. ^{{Cite journal|last=Maskin|first=Eric|last2=Riley|first2=John|date=1984|title=Monopoly with Incomplete Information|journal=The RAND Journal of Economics|volume=15|issue=2|pages=171|doi=10.2307/2555674|issn=0741-6261|jstor=2555674}}
14. ^{{Cite journal|last=Cremer|first=Jacques|last2=Khalil|first2=Fahad|date=1992|title=Gathering Information before Signing a Contract|url=https://ideas.repec.org/a/aea/aecrev/v82y1992i3p566-78.html|journal=American Economic Review|language=en|volume=82|issue=3|pages=566–578}}
15. ^{{Cite journal|last=Crémer|first=Jacques|last2=Khalil|first2=Fahad|last3=Rochet|first3=Jean-Charles|date=1998a|title=Contracts and Productive Information Gathering|journal=Games and Economic Behavior|volume=25|issue=2|pages=174–193|doi=10.1006/game.1998.0651|issn=0899-8256}}
16. ^{{Cite journal|last=Hoppe|first=Eva I.|last2=Schmitz|first2=Patrick W.|date=2013|title=Contracting under Incomplete Information and Social Preferences: An Experimental Study|url=https://ideas.repec.org/a/oup/restud/v80y2013i4p1516-1544.html|journal=Review of Economic Studies|language=en|volume=80|issue=4|pages=1516–1544|doi=10.1093/restud/rdt010}}
17. ^{{Cite journal|last=Hoppe|first=Eva I.|last2=Schmitz|first2=Patrick W.|date=2010|title=The costs and benefits of additional information in agency models with endogenous information structures|journal=Economics Letters|volume=107|issue=1|pages=58–62|doi=10.1016/j.econlet.2009.12.026|issn=0165-1765}}
18. ^{{Cite journal|last=Crémer|first=Jacques|last2=Khalil|first2=Fahad|last3=Rochet|first3=Jean-Charles|date=1998b|title=Strategic Information Gathering before a Contract Is Offered|journal=Journal of Economic Theory|volume=81|issue=1|pages=163–200|doi=10.1006/jeth.1998.2415|issn=0022-0531}}
19. ^{{Cite journal|last=Hoppe|first=Eva I.|date=2013|title=Observability of information acquisition in agency models|journal=Economics Letters|volume=119|issue=1|pages=104–107|doi=10.1016/j.econlet.2013.01.015|issn=0165-1765}}
20. ^{{Cite journal|last=Hoppe|first=Eva I.|last2=Schmitz|first2=Patrick W.|date=2013|title=Public-private partnerships versus traditional procurement: Innovation incentives and information gathering|journal=The RAND Journal of Economics|language=en|volume=44|issue=1|pages=56–74|doi=10.1111/1756-2171.12010|issn=0741-6261|url=https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/41966/1/MPRA_paper_41966.pdf}}
21. ^{{Cite journal|last=Khalil|first=Fahad|last2=Kim|first2=Doyoung|last3=Shin|first3=Dongsoo|date=2006|title=Optimal Task Design: To Integrate or Separate Planning and Implementation?|journal=Journal of Economics & Management Strategy|language=en|volume=15|issue=2|pages=457–478|doi=10.1111/j.1530-9134.2006.00107.x|issn=1058-6407|citeseerx=10.1.1.186.157}}
22. ^The tools used to create information asymmetries are described in the following article http://ssrn.com/abstract=2383166
23. ^Saxton, G. D. and A. E. Anker (2013). "The Aggregate Effects of Decentralized Knowledge Production: Financial Bloggers and Information Asymmetries in the Stock Market." Journal of Communication 63(6): 1054-1069.
24. ^{{cite book |last1=Marwala |first1= Tshilidzi| last2=Hurwitz |first2= Evan |title=Artificial Intelligence and Economic Theory: Skynet in the Market |year=2017 |publisher=Springer |location=London |isbn=978-3-319-66104-9}}
25. ^{{cite web|url=https://blogs.cornell.edu/info2040/2015/11/26/artificial-intelligence-can-reduce-information-asymmetry/|title=Artificial Intelligence can Reduce Information Asymmetry : Networks Course blog for INFO 2040/CS 2850/Econ 2040/SOC 2090|author=|date=|website=blogs.cornell.edu|accessdate=5 April 2018}}

References

  • {{Cite journal |last=Aboody |first=David |last2=Lev |first2=Baruch |year=2000 |title=Information Asymmetry, R&D, and Insider Gains |periodical=Journal of Finance |volume=55 |issue=6 |pages=2747–2766 |url= |doi=10.1111/0022-1082.00305 }}
  • {{Cite journal |last=Brown |first=Stephen |last2=Hillegeist |first2=Stephen |last3=Lo |first3=Kin |year=2004 |title=Conference calls and information asymmetry |periodical=Journal of Accounting and Economics |volume=37 |issue=3 |pages=343–366 |url= |doi=10.1016/j.jacceco.2004.02.001 }}
  • {{cite journal |last=Akerlof |first=George A. |year=1970 |title=The Market for 'Lemons': Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism |journal=Quarterly Journal of Economics |volume=84 |issue=3 |pages=488–500 |doi= 10.2307/1879431|jstor=1879431}}
  • {{Cite journal |last=Hayes |first=Beth |year=1984 |title=Unions and Strikes with Asymmetric Information |periodical=Journal of Labor Economics |volume=2 |issue=1 |pages=57–83 |jstor=2535017 |doi=10.1086/298023 |publisher=[University of Chicago Press, Society of Labor Economists, NORC at the University of Chicago] }}
  • {{cite journal|last=Ikenberry|first=G. John|title=Causes of War: Power and the Roots of International Conflict by Stephen Van Evers|journal=Foreign Affairs|year=1999|volume=78|issue=4|pages=128–9|jstor=20049381|doi=10.2307/20049381}}
  • {{Cite journal |last=Izquierdo |first=Segismundo S. |last2=Izquierdo |first2=Luis R. |year=2007 |title=The impact of quality uncertainty without asymmetric information on market efficiency |periodical=Journal of Business Research |volume=60 |issue=8 |pages=858–867 |url= |issn= 0148-2963|doi=10.1016/j.jbusres.2007.02.010 |citeseerx=10.1.1.412.9956 }}
  • {{cite book

|last1=Jackson|first1=Matthew O.|last2=Morelli|first2=Massimo|editor1-last=Coyne|editor1-first=Chris J.|chapter=The Reasons for Wars – an Updated Survey|pp=34–57|editor2-last=Mathers|editor2-first=Rachel L.|title=The Handbook on the Political Economy of War|publisher=Edward Elgar Publishing|year=2011|isbn=978-1849808323}}
  • {{cite book |title=Microeconomic Theory |last=Mas-Colell |first=Andreu |authorlink= Andreu Mas-Colell|author2=Whinston, Michael D. |author3=Green, Jerry R. |year=1995 |publisher=Oxford University Press |location=New York |isbn=978-0-19-507340-9 |pages= |url= }} (Chaps. 13 and 14 discuss applications of adverse selection and moral hazard models to contract theory.)
  • {{Cite journal |last=Saxton |first=Gregory |last2=Anker |first2=Ashley |title=The Aggregate Effects of Decentralized Knowledge Production: Financial Bloggers and Information Asymmetries in the Stock Market |periodical=Journal of Communication |volume=63 |issue=6 |pages=1054–1069 |doi=10.1111/jcom.12060|publisher=Wiley Subscription Services, Inc|year=2013 }}
  • {{Cite journal |last=Spence |first=Michael |year=1973 |title=Job Market Signaling |periodical=Quarterly Journal of Economics |volume=87 |issue=3 |pages=355–374 |jstor=1882010 |doi=10.2307/1882010 |publisher=The MIT Press }}
  • {{Cite journal |last=Stigler |first=George J. |year=1961 |title=The Economics of Information |periodical=Journal of Political Economy |volume=69 |issue=3 |pages=213–225 |jstor=1829263 |doi=10.1086/258464 |publisher=University of Chicago Press }}

External links

  • [https://www.nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/economic-sciences/laureates/2001/ "The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 2001"] – Official Prize announcement by the Nobel Foundation, nobelprize.org, October 2001. Accessed November 12, 2007. (Related links.)
  • The Economist: Information asymmetry, Secrets and agents, [https://www.economist.com/news/economics-brief/21702428-george-akerlofs-1970-paper-market-lemons-foundation-stone-information]

4 : Asymmetric information|Asymmetry|Law and economics|Market failure

随便看

 

开放百科全书收录14589846条英语、德语、日语等多语种百科知识,基本涵盖了大多数领域的百科知识,是一部内容自由、开放的电子版国际百科全书。

 

Copyright © 2023 OENC.NET All Rights Reserved
京ICP备2021023879号 更新时间:2024/11/12 13:00:06