词条 | Information cascade | |||||||||||
释义 |
Informational (or information) cascades happen when Internet users start passing on information they assume to be true, but cannot know to be true, based on information on what other users are doing. Information cascades can be accelerated by search engines' ranking technologies and their tendency to return results relevant to a user's previous interests. This type of information spreading is hard to stop. Information cascades over social media and the Internet may also be harmless, and may contain truthful information. An information cascade is generally accepted as a two-step process. For a cascade to begin an individual must encounter a scenario with a decision, typically a binary one. Second, outside factors can influence this decision (typically, through the observation of actions and their outcomes of other individuals in similar scenarios). Due to this influence, researchers have drawn comparisons between information cascades and herd behavior.[1] The two-step process of an informational cascade can be broken down into five basic components: 1. There is a decision to be made – for example; whether to adopt a new technology, wear a new style of clothing, eat in a new restaurant, or support a particular political position 2. A limited action space exists (e.g. an adopt/reject decision) 3. People make the decision sequentially, and each person can observe the choices made by those who acted earlier 4. Each person has some information aside from their own that helps guide their decision 5. A person can't directly observe the outside information that other people know, but he or she can make inferences about this information from what they do Social perspectives of cascades, which suggest that agents may act irrationally (e.g., against what they think is optimal) when social pressures are great, exist as complements to the concept of information cascades.[2] More often the problem is that the concept of an information cascade is confused with ideas that do not match the two key conditions of the process, such as social proof, information diffusion,[3] and social influence. Indeed, the term information cascade has even been used to refer to such processes.[4] Basic modelQualitative exampleInformation cascades occur when external information obtained from previous participants in an event overrides one's own private signal, irrespective of the correctness of the former over the latter. The experiment conducted in[5] is a useful example of this process. The experiment consisted of two urns labeled A and B. Urn A contains two balls labeled "a" and one labeled "b". Urn B contains one ball labeled "a" and two labeled "b". The urn from which a ball must be drawn during each run is determined randomly and with equal probabilities (from the throw of a die). The contents of the chosen urn are emptied into a neutral container. The participants are then asked in random order to draw a marble from this container. This entire process may be termed a "run", and a number of such runs are performed. Each time a participant picks up a marble, he is to decide which urn it belongs to. His decision is then announced for the benefit of the remaining participants in the room. Thus, the (n+1)th participant has information about the decisions made by all the n participants preceding him, and also his private signal which is the label on the ball that he draws during his turn. The experimenters observed that an information cascade was observed in 41 of 56 such runs. This means, in the runs where the cascade occurred, at least one participant gave precedence to earlier decisions over his own private signal. It is possible for such an occurrence to produce the wrong result. This phenomenon is known as "Reverse Cascade". Quantitative descriptionA person's signal telling them to accept is denoted as {{mvar|H}} (a high signal, where high signifies he should accept), and a signal telling them not to accept is {{mvar|L}} (a low signal). The model assumes that when the correct decision is to accept, individuals will be more likely to see an {{mvar|H}}, and conversely, when the correct decision is to reject, individuals are more likely to see an {{mvar|L}} signal. This is essentially a conditional probability – the probability of {{mvar|H}} when the correct action is to accept, or . Similarly is the probability that an agent gets an {{mvar|L}} signal when the correct action is reject. If these likelihoods are represented by q, then q > 0.5. This is summarized in the table below.[6]
The first agent determines whether or not to accept solely based on his own signal. As the model assumes that all agents act rationally, the action (accept or reject) the agent feels is more likely is the action he will choose to take. This decision can be explained using Bayes' rule: If the agent receives an {{mvar|H}} signal, then the likelihood of accepting is obtained by calculating . The equation says that, by virtue of the fact that q > 0.5, the first agent, acting only on his private signal, will always increase his estimate of p with an {{mvar|H}} signal. Similarly, it can be shown that an agent will always decrease his expectation of p when he receives a low signal. Recalling that, if the value, {{mvar|V}}, of accepting is equal to the value of rejecting, then an agent will accept if he believes p > 0.5, and reject otherwise. Because this agent started out with the assumption that both accepting and rejecting are equally viable options (p = 0.5), the observation of an {{mvar|H}} signal will allow him to conclude that accepting is the rational choice. The second agent then considers both the first agent's decision and his own signal, again in a rational fashion. In general, the nth agent considers the decisions of the previous n-1 agents, and his own signal. He makes a decision based on Bayesian reasoning to determine the most rational choice. Where {{mvar|a}} is the number of accepts in the previous set plus the agent's own signal, and {{mvar|b}} is the number of rejects. Thus, {{tmath|1=a + b = n}}. The decision is based on how the value on the right hand side of the equation compares with p.[6] Explicit model assumptionsThe original model makes several assumptions about human behavior and the world in which humans act,[7] some of which are relaxed in later versions[6] or in alternate definitions of similar problems, such as the diffusion of innovations.
Resulting conditions
RespondingA literature exists that examines how individuals or firms might respond to the existence of informational cascades when they have products to sell but where buyers are unsure of the quality of those products. Curtis Taylor (1999)[9] shows that when selling a house the seller might wish to start with high prices, as failure to sell with low prices is indicative of low quality and might start a cascade on not buying, while failure to sell with high prices could be construed as meaning the house is just over-priced, and prices can then be reduced to get a sale. Daniel Sgroi (2002)[10] shows that firms might use "guinea pigs" who are given the opportunity to buy early to kick-start an informational cascade through their early and public purchasing decisions, and work by David Gill and Daniel Sgroi (2008)[11] show that early public tests might have a similar effect (and in particular that passing a "tough test" which is biased against the seller can instigate a cascade all by itself). Bose et al.[12] have examined how prices set by a monopolist might evolve in the presence of potential cascade behavior where the monopolist and consumers are unsure of a products quality. Examples and fields of applicationInformation cascades occur in situations where seeing many people make the same choice provides evidence that outweighs one's own judgment. That is, one thinks: "It's more likely that I'm wrong than that all those other people are wrong. Therefore, I will do as they do." In what has been termed a reputational cascade, late responders sometimes go along with the decisions of early responders, not just because the late responders think the early responders are right, but also because they perceive their reputation will be damaged if they dissent from the early responders.[13] Market cascadesInformation cascades have become one of the topics of behavioral economics, as they are often seen in financial markets where they can feed speculation and create cumulative and excessive price moves, either for the whole market (market bubble) or a specific asset, like a stock that becomes overly popular among investors. Marketers also use the idea of cascades to attempt to get a buying cascade started for a new product. If they can induce an initial set of people to adopt the new product, then those who make purchasing decisions later on may also adopt the product even if it is no better than, or perhaps even worse than, competing products. This is most effective if these later consumers are able to observe the adoption decisions, but not how satisfied the early customers actually were with the choice. This is consistent with the idea that cascades arise naturally when people can see what others do but not what they know.[14] Information cascades are usually considered by economists:
Social network analysisDotey et al.[15] state that information flows in the form of cascades on the social network. According to the authors, analysis of virality of information cascades on a social network may lead to many useful applications like determining the most influential individuals within a network. This information can be used for maximizing market effectiveness or influencing public opinion. Various structural and temporal features of a network affect cascade virality. In contrast to work on information cascades in social networks, the Social Influence Model of belief spread argues that people have some notion of the private beliefs of those in their network.[16] The social influence model, then, relaxes the assumption of information cascades that people are acting only on observable actions taken by others. In addition, the social influence model focuses on embedding people within a social network, as opposed to a queue. Finally, the social influence model relaxes the assumption of the information cascade model that people will either complete an action or not by allowing for a continuous scale of the "strength" of an agents belief that an action should be completed. Historical examples
Empirical StudiesIn addition to the examples above, Information Cascades have been shown to exist in several empirical studies. Perhaps the best example, given above, is.[5] Participants stood in a line behind an urn which had balls of different colors. Sequentially, participants would pick a ball out of the urn, looks at it, and then places it back into the urn. The agent then voices their opinion of which color of balls (red or blue) there is a majority of in the urn for the rest of the participants to hear. Participants get a monetary reward if they guess correctly, forcing the concept of rationality. Other examples include
Legal aspectsThe negative effects of informational cascades sometimes become a legal concern and laws have been enacted to neutralize them. Ward Farnsworth, a law professor, analyzed the legal aspects of informational cascades and gave several examples in his book The Legal Analyst: in many military courts, the officers voting to decide a case vote in reverse rank order (the officer of the lowest rank votes first), and he suggested it may be done so the lower-ranked officers would not be tempted by the cascade to vote with the more senior officers, who are believed to have more accurate judgement; another example is that countries such as Israel and France have laws that prohibit polling days or weeks before elections to prevent the effect of informational cascade that may influence the election results.[22] GlobalizationAs previously stated, informational cascades are logical processes describing how an individual’s decision process changes based upon outside information. Cascades have never been a household name; at best, they exist hypothetically. Over the past few decades, cascades saw an increase in popularity through various fields of study. Specifically, they have been quite useful in comparing thought processes between Greek and German organic farmers. The aforementioned study suggests discrepancies between Greek and German thought processes based upon their cultural and socioeconomic differences.[23] Even further, cascades have been extrapolated to ideas such as financial volatility and monetary policy. In 2004 Helmut Wagner and Wolfram Berger suggested cascades as an analytical vehicle to examine changes to the financial market as it became more globalized. Wagner and Berger noticed structural changes to the framework of understanding financial markets due to globalization; giving rise to volatility in capital flow and spawning uncertainty which affected central banks.[24] Additionally, information cascades are useful in understanding the origins of terrorist tactics. When the attack by Black September occurred in 1972 it was hard not to see the similarities between their tactics and the Baader-Meinhof group (also known as the Red Army Faction [RAF]).[25] All of these examples portray how the process of cascades were put into use. Moreover, it is important to understand the framework of cascades to move forward in a more globalized society. Establishing a foundation to understanding the passage of information through transnational and multinational organizations, and even more, is critical to the arising modern society.[26] Summing up all of these points, cascades, as a general term, encompass a spectrum of different concepts. Information cascades have been the underlying thread in how information is transferred, overwritten, and understood through various cultures spanning from a multitude of different countries.[27] See also
References1. ^{{Cite journal|last=Duan|first=Wenjing|last2=Gu|first2=Bin|last3=Whinston|first3=Andrew B.|date=2008-03-01|title=Informational Cascades and Software Adoption on the Internet: An Empirical Investigation|url=https://papers.ssrn.com/abstract=1103165|location=Rochester, NY}} 2. ^{{cite journal | last1 = Schiller | first1 = R.J. | year = 1995 | title = Conversation, Information and Herd Behavior | url = | journal = Rhetoric and Economic Behavior | volume = 85 | issue = 3| pages = 181–185 }} 3. ^{{cite book | last1 = Gruhl | first1 = Daniel | last2 = Guha | first2 = R. | last3 = Liben-Nowell | first3 = D. | last4 = Tomkins | first4 = A. | year = 2004 | title = Information diffusion through blogspace | url = | journal = WWW | volume = | issue = | pages = 491–501 | doi = 10.1145/988672.988739 | isbn = 978-1581138443 | citeseerx = 10.1.1.131.4532 }} 4. ^Sadikov, E.; Medina, M.; Leskovec, J.; Garcia-Molina, H. (2011). "Correcting for Missing Data in Information Cascades" (PDF). WSDM. Retrieved March 23, 2012. 5. ^1 {{cite journal|last=Anderson|first=L.R.|author2=Holt, C.A.|title=Information Cascades in the Laboratory|journal=The American Economic Review|year=1997|volume=87|issue=5|pages=847–862}} 6. ^1 2 {{cite book|url=http://www.cs.cornell.edu/home/kleinber/networks-book/|title=Networks, Crowds and Markets: Reasoning about a Highly Connected Workld|last=Easley|first=David|publisher=Cambridge University Press|year=2010|pages=483–506}} 7. ^1 2 Bikhchandani, S., Hirshleifer, D., and Welch, I. (1992), "A Theory of Fads, Fashion, Custom, and Cultural Change as Informational Cascades," Journal of Political Economy, Volume 100, Issue 5, pp. pp. 992-1026. {{webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20110713060849/http://www.irvinehousingblog.com/wp-content/uploads/2008/03/atheoryoffads.pdf |date=2011-07-13 }} + button to enlarge. 8. ^{{cite book|last=Newell|first=A.|title=Human problem solving|year=1972|publisher=Prentice Hall|location=Englewood Cliffs, NY}} 9. ^{{cite journal|last=Taylor|first=C.|title=Time-on-the-Market as a Sign of Quality.|journal=Review of Economic Studies|year=1999|volume=66|issue=3|pages=555–578|doi=10.1111/1467-937x.00098}} 10. ^{{cite journal|last=Sgroi|first=D.|year=2002|title=Optimizing Information in the Herd: Guinea Pigs, Profits, and Welfare|url=http://wrap.warwick.ac.uk/50142/1/WRAP_Sgroi_Paper9.pdf|journal=Games and Economic Behavior|volume=39|pages=137–166|doi=10.1006/game.2001.0881|via=}} 11. ^{{cite journal|last=Gill|first=D.|author2=D. Sgroi|title=Sequential Decisions with Tests.|journal=Games and Economic Behavior|year=2008|volume=63|issue=2|pages=663–678|doi=10.1016/j.geb.2006.07.004|citeseerx=10.1.1.322.7566}} 12. ^{{cite journal|last=Bose|first=S.|author2=G. Orosel |author3=M. Ottaviani |author4=L. Vesterlund |title=Dynamic Monopoly Pricing and Herding.|journal=RAND Journal of Economics|year=2006|volume=37|issue=4|pages=910–928 |doi=10.1111/j.1756-2171.2006.tb00063.x|citeseerx=10.1.1.493.1834}} 13. ^Pierre Lemieux (2003), "Following the Herd", Regulation, Cato Institute, 21. {{cite web |url=http://www.cato.org/pubs/regulation/regv26n4/v26n4-2.pdf |title=Archived copy |accessdate=2010-07-14 |deadurl=yes |archiveurl=https://web.archive.org/web/20100616042143/http://www.cato.org/pubs/regulation/regv26n4/v26n4-2.pdf |archivedate=2010-06-16 |df= }}. Retrieved 14 July 2010. 14. ^http://research.ivo-welch.info/palgrave.pdf{{dead link|date=December 2017 |bot=InternetArchiveBot |fix-attempted=yes }} 15. ^Dotey, A., Rom, H. and Vaca C., Information Diffusion in Social Media. 2011, Stanford University 16. ^{{cite book|last=Friedkin|first=N.E. and Johnsen, E.C.|title=Social Influence Network Theory: A Sociological Examination of Small Group Dynamics|year=2011|publisher=Cambridge University Press}} 17. ^1 2 3 {{cite book | last = Shirky | first = Clay | authorlink = Clay Shirky | title = Here Comes Everybody: The Power of Organizing Without Organizations | publisher = Penguin Press | location = New York | year = 2008 | pages = 161–164 | doi = | isbn = 978-1-59420-153-0 | title-link = Here Comes Everybody: The Power of Organizing Without Organizations }} 18. ^{{cite journal| last = Carboneau| first = Clark| title = Using Diffusion of Innovations and Academic Detailing to Spread Evidence-based Practices| doi = 10.1111/j.1945-1474.2005.tb01117.x| journal = Journal for Healthcare Quality| volume=27| issue = 2| year=2005| pages=48–52}} 19. ^{{cite paper |title = The Diffusion Process |author = Beal, George M. |author2 = Bohlen, Joe M. |url = http://www.soc.iastate.edu/extension/presentations/publications/comm/Diffusion%20Process.pdf |format = PDF |accessdate = 2008-11-11 |publisher = Iowa State University of Science and Technology of Ames, Iowa |deadurl = yes |archiveurl = https://web.archive.org/web/20090408212658/http://www.soc.iastate.edu/extension/presentations/publications/comm/Diffusion%20Process.pdf |archivedate = 2009-04-08 |df = }} 20. ^{{cite journal|last=De Vany|first=A.|author2=D. Walls|title=Uncertainty in the movie industry: does star power reduce the terror of the box office?|journal=Journal of Cultural Economics|year=1999|volume=23|issue=4|pages=285–318|doi=10.1023/a:1007608125988}} 21. ^{{cite journal|last=Walden|first=Eric|author2=Glenn Browne|title=Information Cascades in the Adoption of New Technology|journal=ICIS Proceedings|year=2002|url=http://aisel.aisnet.org/icis2002/40/}} 22. ^Farnsworth, Ward (2007). The Legal Analyst: A Toolkit for Thinking about the Law. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. {{ISBN|0-226-23835-0}} 23. ^{{Cite journal|last=Chatzimichael|first=Konstantinos|last2=Genius|first2=Margarita|last3=Tzouvelekas|first3=Vangelis|date=2013-07-03|title=Informational cascades and technology adoption: Evidence from Greek and German organic growers|journal=Journal of Food Policy|volume=49|pages=186–195|doi=10.1016/j.foodpol.2014.08.001}} 24. ^{{Cite journal|last=Wagner|first=Helmut|last2=Berger|first2=Wolfram|date=2004-06-01|title=Globalization, Financial Volatility and Monetary Policy|journal=Empirica|language=en|volume=31|issue=2–3|pages=163–184|doi=10.1007/s10633-004-0915-4|issn=0340-8744|citeseerx=10.1.1.466.2938}} 25. ^{{Cite book|title=Ulrike Meinhof and the Red Army Faction : performing terrorism|last=1981-|first=Passmore, Leith|isbn=9780230370777|edition=First|location=New York|oclc=904285976|date = 2011-11-03}} 26. ^{{Cite journal|last=Hamlett|first=Patrick W.|last2=Cobb|first2=Michael D.|date=2006-11-01|title=Potential Solutions to Public Deliberation Problems: Structured Deliberations and Polarization Cascades|journal=Policy Studies Journal|language=en|volume=34|issue=4|pages=629–648|doi=10.1111/j.1541-0072.2006.00195.x|issn=1541-0072}} 27. ^{{Cite journal|last=Drezner|first=Daniel W.|date=2010|title=Weighing the Scales: The Internet's Effect On State-Society Relations|journal=The Brown Journal of World Affairs|volume=16|issue=2|pages=31–44|jstor=24590907}} External links
3 : Behavioral finance|Conformity|Information |
|||||||||||
随便看 |
|
开放百科全书收录14589846条英语、德语、日语等多语种百科知识,基本涵盖了大多数领域的百科知识,是一部内容自由、开放的电子版国际百科全书。