请输入您要查询的百科知识:

 

词条 Max Weber
释义

  1. Biography

      Early life and family background    Education    Early work   Later work  Political involvements  Last years 

  2. Max Weber's thought

     Max Weber's bureaucratic model (rational-legal model)  Inspirations  Methodology  Rationalisation  Sociology of religion  The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism  The Religion of China: Confucianism and Taoism  The Religion of India: The Sociology of Hinduism and Buddhism  Ancient Judaism  Economy and Society  Theodicy of fortune and misfortune  Politics and government  Social stratification  Study of the city  Economics  Methodological individualism  Marginalism and psychophysics  Economic history  Economic calculation 

  3. Legacy

  4. Critical responses to Weber

  5. Works

  6. See also

  7. References

     Sources 

  8. Further reading

  9. External links

{{other people}}{{good article}}{{Use British English|date= April 2011}}{{Use dmy dates|date=April 2013}}{{Infobox scientist
| birth_name = Maximilian Karl Emil Weber
| image = Max Weber 1894.jpg
| caption = Weber in 1894
| birth_date = {{birth date |1864|4|21|df= y}}
| birth_place = {{nowrap|Erfurt, Province of Saxony, Prussia}}
| death_date = {{death date and age |1920|6|14|1864|4|21|df= y}}
| death_place = Munich, Bavaria, Germany
| nationality = Prussia (1864–1871)
German Empire (1871–1918)
Weimar Republic (1918–1920)
| fields = {{hlist |Economics |sociology |history |law |politics |philosophy}}
| workplaces = {{hlist |Universities of Berlin |Freiburg |Heidelberg |Vienna |Munich}}
| alma_mater = University of Berlin
University of Heidelberg
| doctoral_advisor = Levin Goldschmidt
| academic_advisors =
| notable_students =
| known_for = {{unbulleted list |Weberian bureaucracy |Disenchantment{{·}}Ideal type |Iron cage{{·}}Life chances |Methodological individualism |Monopoly on violence |Protestant work ethic |Rationalisation{{·}}Social action |{{nowrap |Three-component stratification}} |{{nowrap |Tripartite classification of authority}} |Verstehen |Instrumental and intrinsic value |Instrumental and value rationality}}
| influences = {{unbulleted list|Hermann Baumgarten[1]{{·}}Immanuel Kant{{·}}Niccolò Machiavelli[2]{{·}}Karl Marx{{·}}Charles Darwin{{·}}Sigmund Freud{{·}}Friedrich Nietzsche{{·}}Wilhelm Dilthey{{·}}Heinrich Rickert{{·}}John Stuart Mill[3]{{·}}Georg Simmel{{·}}Werner Sombart[4]{{·}}Ernst Troeltsch[3]}}
| influenced = {{unbulleted list|Karl Jaspers{{·}}Georg Simmel{{·}}Talcott Parsons{{·}}Ludwig von Mises{{·}}György Lukács{{·}}Theodor W. Adorno{{·}}Carl Schmitt{{·}}Jürgen Habermas{{·}}Joseph Schumpeter{{·}}C. Wright Mills{{·}}Cornelius Castoriadis{{·}}Ludwig Lachmann{{·}}Karl Polanyi}}
| awards =
| signature = | footnotes =
}}Maximilian Karl Emil Weber ({{IPAc-en|ˈ|v|eɪ|b|ər}};[5] {{IPA-de|ˈveːbɐ|lang}}; 21 April 1864 – 14 June 1920) was a German sociologist, philosopher, jurist, and political economist. His ideas profoundly influenced social theory and social research.[6] Weber is often cited, with Émile Durkheim and Karl Marx, as among the three founders of sociology.[8][9][7][8][9] Weber was a key proponent of methodological anti-positivism, arguing for the study of social action through interpretive (rather than purely empiricist) means, based on understanding the purpose and meaning that individuals attach to their own actions. Unlike Durkheim, he did not believe in mono-causality and rather proposed that for any outcome there can be multiple causes.[10]

Weber's main intellectual concern was understanding the processes of rationalisation, secularisation, and "disenchantment" that he associated with the rise of capitalism and modernity.[14] He saw these as the result of a new way of thinking about the world.[11] Weber is best known for his thesis combining economic sociology and the sociology of religion, elaborated in his book The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism, in which he proposed that ascetic Protestantism was one of the major "elective affinities" associated with the rise in the Western world of market-driven capitalism and the rational-legal nation-state. He argued that it was in the basic tenets of Protestantism to boost capitalism. Thus, it can be said that the spirit of capitalism is inherent to Protestant religious values.

Against Marx's historical materialism, Weber emphasised the importance of cultural influences embedded in religion as a means for understanding the genesis of capitalism.[12] The Protestant Ethic formed the earliest part in Weber's broader investigations into world religion; he went on to examine the religions of China, the religions of India and ancient Judaism, with particular regard to their differing economic consequences and conditions of social stratification.{{Ref label |a|a|none}} In another major work, "Politics as a Vocation", Weber defined the state as an entity that successfully claims a "monopoly of the legitimate use of physical force within a given territory". He was also the first to categorise social authority into distinct forms, which he labelled as charismatic, traditional, and rational-legal. His analysis of bureaucracy emphasised that modern state institutions are increasingly based on rational-legal authority.

Weber also made a variety of other contributions in economic history, as well as economic theory and methodology. Weber's analysis of modernity and rationalisation significantly influenced the critical theory associated with the Frankfurt School. After the First World War, Max Weber was among the founders of the liberal German Democratic Party. He also ran unsuccessfully for a seat in parliament and served as advisor to the committee that drafted the ill-fated democratic Weimar Constitution of 1919. After contracting Spanish flu, he died of pneumonia in 1920, aged 56.[8]

Biography

Early life and family background

Karl Emil Maximilian Weber was born in 1864, in Erfurt, Province of Saxony, Prussia.[8] He was the oldest of the seven children of Max Weber Sr., a wealthy and prominent civil servant and member of the National Liberal Party, and his wife Helene (Fallenstein), who partly descended from French Huguenot immigrants and held strong moral absolutist ideas.[8]

Weber Sr.'s involvement in public life immersed his home in both politics and academia, as his salon welcomed many prominent scholars and public figures.[8] The young Weber and his brother Alfred, who also became a sociologist and economist, thrived in this intellectual atmosphere. Weber's 1876 Christmas presents to his parents, when he was thirteen years old, were two historical essays entitled "About the course of German history, with special reference to the positions of the Emperor and the Pope", and "About the Roman Imperial period from Constantine to the migration of nations".[13] In class, bored and unimpressed with the teachers—who in turn resented what they perceived as a disrespectful attitude—he secretly read all forty volumes of Goethe,[22][23] and it has been recently argued that this was an important influence on his thought and methodology.[14] Before entering the university, he would read many other classical works.[23] Over time, Weber would also be significantly affected by the marital tension between his father, "a man who enjoyed earthly pleasures", and his mother, a devout Calvinist "who sought to lead an ascetic life".[26][27]

Education

In 1882 Weber enrolled in the University of Heidelberg as a law student.[28] After a year of military service, he transferred to the University of Berlin.[22] After his first few years as a student, during which he spent much time "drinking beer and fencing", Weber would increasingly take his mother's side in family arguments and grew estranged from his father.[26][27][32] Simultaneously with his studies, he worked as a junior lawyer.[22] In 1886 Weber passed the examination for Referendar, comparable to the bar association examination in the British and American legal systems. Throughout the late 1880s, Weber continued his study of law and history.[22] He earned his law doctorate in 1889 by writing a dissertation on legal history titled The history of commercial partnerships in the Middle Ages. This work was used as part of a longer work On the History of Trading Companies in the Middle Ages, based on South-European Sources, published in the same year.[15] Two years later, Weber completed his Habilitationsschrift, Roman Agrarian History and its Significance for Public and Private Law, working with August Meitzen.[36][37] Having thus become a Privatdozent, Weber joined the University of Berlin's faculty, lecturing and consulting for the government.[38]

Early work

In the years between the completion of his dissertation and habilitation, Weber took an interest in contemporary social policy. In 1888 he joined the Verein für Socialpolitik,[39] a new professional association of German economists affiliated with the historical school, who saw the role of economics primarily as finding solutions to the social problems of the age and who pioneered large scale statistical studies of economic issues. He also involved himself in politics, joining the left-leaning Evangelical Social Congress.[40] In 1890 the Verein established a research program to examine "the Polish question" or Ostflucht: the influx of Polish farm workers into eastern Germany as local labourers migrated to Germany's rapidly industrialising cities.[8] Weber was put in charge of the study and wrote a large part of the final report,[8][39] which generated considerable attention and controversy and marked the beginning of Weber's renown as a social scientist.[8] From 1893 to 1899 Weber was a member of the Alldeutscher Verband (Pan-German League), an organization that campaigned against the influx of the Polish workers; the degree of Weber's support for the Germanisation of Poles and similar nationalist policies is still debated by modern scholars.[45][46] In some of his work, in particular his provocative lecture on "The Nation State and Economic Policy" delivered in 1895, Weber criticises the immigration of Poles and blames the Junker class for perpetuating Slavic immigration to serve their selfish interests.[16]

Also in 1893 he married his distant cousin Marianne Schnitger, later a feminist activist and author in her own right,[8][49] who was instrumental in collecting and publishing Weber's journal articles as books after his death, while her biography of him is an important source for understanding Weber's life.[50][51] They would have no children.[32] The marriage granted long-awaited financial independence to Weber, allowing him to finally leave his parents' household.[27] The couple moved to Freiburg in 1894, where Weber was appointed professor of economics at the university,[37][38] before accepting the same position at the University of Heidelberg in 1896.[37][38] There Weber became a central figure in the so-called "Weber Circle", composed of other intellectuals such as his wife Marianne, Georg Jellinek, Ernst Troeltsch, Werner Sombart and Robert Michels.[8] Weber also remained active in the Verein and the Evangelical Social Congress.[8] His research in that period was focused on economics and legal history.[60]

In 1897 Max Weber Sr. died two months after a severe quarrel with his son that was never resolved.[8][62] After this, Weber became increasingly prone to depression, nervousness and insomnia, making it difficult for him to fulfill his duties as a professor.[22][37] His condition forced him to reduce his teaching and eventually leave his course unfinished in the autumn of 1899. After spending months in a sanatorium during the summer and autumn of 1900, Weber and his wife travelled to Italy at the end of the year and did not return to Heidelberg until April 1902. He would again withdraw from teaching in 1903 and not return to it till 1919. Weber's ordeal with mental illness was carefully described in a personal chronology that was destroyed by his wife. This chronicle was supposedly destroyed because Marianne Weber feared that Max Weber's work would be discredited by the Nazis if his experience with mental illness were widely known.[8][17]

Later work

After Weber's immense productivity in the early 1890s, he did not publish any papers between early 1898 and late 1902, finally resigning his professorship in late 1903. Freed from those obligations, in that year he accepted a position as associate editor of the Archives for Social Science and Social Welfare,[67] where he worked with his colleagues {{Interlanguage link multi|Edgar Jaffé|de}} and Werner Sombart.[8][69] His new interests would lie in more fundamental issues of social sciences; his works from this latter period are of primary interest to modern scholars.[60] In 1904, Weber began to publish some of his most seminal papers in this journal, notably his essay The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism, which became his most famous work[71] and laid the foundations for his later research on the impact of cultures and religions on the development of economic systems.[18] This essay was the only one of his works from that period that was published as a book during his lifetime. Some other of his works written in the first one and a half decades of the 20th century—published posthumously and dedicated primarily from the fields of sociology of religion, economic and legal sociology—are also recognised as among his most important intellectual contributions.[8]

Also in 1904, he visited the United States and participated in the Congress of Arts and Sciences held in connection with the World's Fair (Louisiana Purchase Exposition) in St. Louis. A monument to his visit was placed at the home of relatives whom Weber visited in Mt. Airy, North Carolina.[19]

Despite his partial recovery evident in America, Weber felt that he was unable to resume regular teaching at that time and continued on as a private scholar, helped by an inheritance in 1907.[38][67] In 1909, disappointed with the Verein, he co-founded the German Sociological Association (Deutsche Gesellschaft für Soziologie, or DGS) and served as its first treasurer.[8] He would, however, resign from the DGS in 1912.[8] In 1912, Weber tried to organise a left-wing political party to combine social-democrats and liberals. This attempt was unsuccessful, in part because many liberals feared social-democratic revolutionary ideals.[79]

Political involvements

At the outbreak of World War I, Weber, aged 50, volunteered for service and was appointed as a reserve officer and put in charge of organizing the army hospitals in Heidelberg, a role he fulfilled until the end of 1915.[67][81] Weber's views on the war and the expansion of the German empire changed during the course of the conflict.[79][81][20] Early on he supported the nationalist rhetoric and the war effort, though with some hesitation as he viewed the war as a necessity to fulfill German duty as a leading state power. In time, however, Weber became one of the most prominent critics of German expansionism and of the Kaiser's war policies.[8] He publicly attacked the Belgian annexation policy and unrestricted submarine warfare and later supported calls for constitutional reform, democratisation and universal suffrage.[8]

Weber joined the worker and soldier council of Heidelberg in 1918. He then served in the German delegation to the Paris Peace Conference and as advisor to the Confidential Committee for Constitutional Reform, which drafted the Weimar Constitution.[67] Motivated by his understanding of the American model, he advocated a strong, popularly elected presidency as a constitutional counterbalance to the power of the professional bureaucracy.[8] More controversially, he also defended the provisions for emergency presidential powers that became Article 48 of the Weimar Constitution. These provisions were later used by Adolf Hitler to subvert the rest of the constitution and institute rule by decree, allowing his regime to suppress opposition and gain dictatorial powers.[21]

Weber also ran, unsuccessfully, for a parliamentary seat, as a member of the liberal German Democratic Party, which he had co-founded.[8][91] He opposed both the leftist German Revolution of 1918–1919 and the ratification of the Treaty of Versailles, principled positions that defied the political alignments in Germany at that time,[8] and which may have prevented Friedrich Ebert, the new social-democratic President of Germany, from appointing Weber as minister or ambassador.[81] Weber commanded widespread respect but relatively little influence.[8] Weber's role in German politics remains controversial to this day.

In Weber's critique of the left, he complained of the leaders of the leftist Spartacus League—which was led by Karl Liebknecht and Rosa Luxemburg and controlled the city government of Berlin while Weber was campaigning for his party—"We have this [German] revolution to thank for the fact that we cannot send a single division against the Poles. All we see is dirt, muck, dung, and horse-play—nothing else. Liebknecht belongs in the madhouse and Rosa Luxemburg in the zoological gardens." [22] Weber was at the same time critical of the Versailles Treaty, which he believed unjustly assigned "war guilt" to Germany when it came to World War I. Weber believed that many countries were guilty of starting World War I, not just Germany. In making this case, Weber argued that "In the case of this war there is one, and only one power that desired it under all circumstances through its own will and, according to their political goals required: Russia. ... It never crossed [my] mind that a German invasion of Belgium [in 1914] was nothing but an innocent act on the part of the Germans."{{Sfn | Waters | Waters | 2015 | p = 20}}

Later that same month, in January 1919, after Weber and Weber's party were defeated for election, Weber delivered one of his greatest academic lectures, Politics as a Vocation, which reflected on the inherent violence and dishonesty he saw among politicians—a profession in which only recently Weber was so personally active. About the nature of politicians, he concluded that, "In nine out of ten cases they are windbags puffed up with hot air about themselves. They are not in touch with reality, and they do not feel the burden they need to shoulder; they just intoxicate themselves with romantic sensations."{{Sfn | Waters | Waters | 2015 | pp= 21, 196}}

Last years

Frustrated with politics, Weber resumed teaching during this time, first at the University of Vienna, then, after 1919, at the University of Munich.[8][38][67] His lectures from that period were collected into major works, such as the General Economic History, Science as a Vocation and Politics as a Vocation.[8] In Munich, he headed the first German university institute of sociology, but never held a professorial position in sociology. Many colleagues and students in Munich attacked his response to the German Revolution and some right-wing students held protests in front of his home.[79] Max Weber contracted the Spanish flu and died of pneumonia in Munich on 14 June 1920.[8] At the time of his death, Weber had not finished writing his magnum opus on sociological theory: Economy and Society. His widow Marianne helped prepare it for its publication in 1921–22.

Max Weber's thought

Max Weber's bureaucratic theory or model is sometimes also known as the "rational-legal" model. The model tries to explain bureaucracy from a rational point of view via nine main characteristics or principles; these are as follows:[23]

Max Weber's bureaucratic model (rational-legal model)

Weber wrote that the modern bureaucracy in both the public and private sector relies on the following principles.

"First, it is based on the general principle of precisely defined and organized across-the-board competencies of the various offices. These competencies are underpinned by rules, laws, or administrative regulations."[24] For Weber, this means[25]

  1. A rigid division of labor is established that clearly identifies regular tasks and duties of the particular bureaucratic system.
  2. Regulations describe firmly established chains of command and the duties and capacity to coerce others to comply.
  3. Hiring people with particular, certified qualifications supports regular and continuous execution of the assigned duties.

Weber notes that these three aspects "...constitute the essence of bureaucratic administration ... in the public sector. In the private sector, these three aspects constitute the essence of a bureaucratic management of a private company."[26]

Main principles (characteristics):

  1. Specialized roles
  2. Recruitment based on merit (e.g., tested through open competition)
  3. Uniform principles of placement, promotion, and transfer in an administrative system
  4. Careerism with systematic salary structure
  5. Hierarchy, responsibility and accountability
  6. Subjection of official conduct to strict rules of discipline and control
  7. Supremacy of abstract rules
  8. Impersonal authority (e.g., office bearer does not bring the office with him)
  9. Political neutrality

Merits: As Weber noted, real bureaucracy is less optimal and effective than his ideal-type model. Each of Weber's principles can degenerate{{mdash}}and more so, when they are used to analyze the individual level in an organization. But, when implemented in a group setting in an organization, some form of efficiency and effectiveness can be achieved, especially with regard to better output. This is especially true when the Bureaucratic model emphasizes qualification (merits), specialization of job-scope (labour), hierarchy of power, rules and discipline.[27]

Demerits: However, competencies, efficiency and effectiveness can be unclear and contradictory, especially when dealing with oversimplified matters. In a dehumanized bureaucracy, inflexible in distributing the job-scope, with every worker having to specialize from day one without rotating tasks for fear of decreasing output, tasks are often routine and can contribute to boredom. Thus, employees can sometimes feel that they are not part of the organization's work vision and missions. Consequently, they do not have any sense of belonging in the long term. Furthermore, this type of organization tends to invite exploitation and underestimate the potential of the employees, as creativity of the workers is brushed aside in favour of strict adherence to rules, regulations and procedures.[23]

Inspirations

Weber's thinking was strongly influenced by German idealism, and particularly by neo-Kantianism, which he had been exposed to through Heinrich Rickert, his professorial colleague at the University of Freiburg.[8] Especially important to Weber's work is the neo-Kantian belief that reality is essentially chaotic and incomprehensible, with all rational order deriving from the way the human mind focuses attention on certain aspects of reality and organises the resulting perceptions.[8] Weber's opinions regarding the methodology of the social sciences show parallels with the work of contemporary neo-Kantian philosopher and pioneering sociologist Georg Simmel.[28]

Weber was also influenced by Kantian ethics, which he nonetheless came to think of as obsolete in a modern age lacking in religious certainties. In this last respect, the influence of Friedrich Nietzsche's philosophy is evident.[8] According to the Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy, the "deep tension between the Kantian moral imperatives and a Nietzschean diagnosis of the modern cultural world is apparently what gives such a darkly tragic and agnostic shade to Weber's ethical worldview".[8] Another major influence in Weber's life was the writings of Karl Marx and the workings of socialist thought in academia and active politics. While Weber shares some of Marx's consternation with bureaucratic systems and maligns them as being capable of advancing their own logic to the detriment of human freedom and autonomy, Weber views conflict as perpetual and inevitable and does not host the spirit of a materially available utopia.[29] Though the influence of his mother's Calvinist religiosity is evident throughout Weber's life and work, and though he maintained a deep, lifelong interest in the study of religions, Weber was open about the fact that he was personally irreligious.[30][31]

As a political economist and economic historian, Weber belonged to the "youngest" German historical school of economics, represented by academics such as Gustav von Schmoller and his student Werner Sombart. But, even though Weber's research interests were very much in line with that school, his views on methodology and the theory of value diverged significantly from those of other German historicists and were closer, in fact, to those of Carl Menger and the Austrian School, the traditional rivals of the historical school.[116][117] (See section on Economics.)

New research suggests that some of Weber's theories, including his interest in the sociology of Far Eastern religion and elements of his theory of disenchantment, were actually shaped by Weber's interaction with contemporary German occult figures. He is known to have visited the Ordo Templi Orientis at Monte Verità shortly before articulating his idea of disenchantment.[32]{{rp|269–70}} He is known to have met the German poet and occultist Stefan George and developed some elements of his theory of charisma after observing George. However, Weber disagreed with many of George's views and never formally joined George's occult circle.[32]{{rp|290–93}} Weber may have also had his first exposure to Taoism, albeit in a Westernized form, through Gustav Gräser at Monte Verità.[32]{{rp|275–76}} Research on Weber's engagement with the occult has led some German and American scholars{{who|date=October 2018}} to re-interpret his theories of disenchantment.

Methodology

Unlike some other classical figures (Comte, Durkheim) Weber did not attempt, consciously, to create any specific set of rules governing social sciences in general, or sociology in particular.[8] In comparison with Durkheim and Marx, Weber was more focused on individuals and culture and this is clear in his methodology.[22] Whereas Durkheim focused on the society, Weber concentrated on the individuals and their actions (see structure and action discussion) and whereas Marx argued for the primacy of the material world over the world of ideas, Weber valued ideas as motivating actions of individuals, at least in the big picture.[22][125]

Sociology, for Max Weber, is:

{{quote|... a science which attempts the interpretive understanding of social action in order thereby to arrive at a causal explanation of its course and effects.|Max Weber[126]}}

Weber was concerned with the question of objectivity and subjectivity.[8] Weber distinguished social action from social behavior, noting that social action must be understood through how individuals subjectively relate to one another.[8][129] Study of social action through interpretive means (Verstehen) must be based upon understanding the subjective meaning and purpose that individuals attach to their actions.[8][60] Social actions may have easily identifiable and objective means, but much more subjective ends and the understanding of those ends by a scientist is subject to yet another layer of subjective understanding (that of the scientist).[8] Weber noted that the importance of subjectivity in social sciences makes creation of fool-proof, universal laws much more difficult than in natural sciences and that the amount of objective knowledge that social sciences may achieve is precariously limited.[8] Overall, Weber supported the goal of objective science, but he noted that it is an unreachable goal—although one definitely worth striving for.[8]

{{quote|There is no absolutely "objective" scientific analysis of culture. ... All knowledge of cultural reality ... is always knowledge from particular points of view. ... an "objective" analysis of cultural events, which proceeds according to the thesis that the ideal of science is the reduction of empirical reality to "laws", is meaningless ... [because] ... the knowledge of social laws is not knowledge of social reality but is rather one of the various aids used by our minds for attaining this end.|Max Weber, "Objectivity" in Social Science, 1904[33]}}

The principle of methodological individualism, which holds that social scientists should seek to understand collectivities (such as nations, cultures, governments, churches, corporations, etc.) solely as the result and the context of the actions of individual persons, can be traced to Weber, particularly to the first chapter of Economy and Society, in which he argues that only individuals "can be treated as agents in a course of subjectively understandable action".[117][129] In other words, Weber argued that social phenomena can be understood scientifically only to the extent that they are captured by models of the behaviour of purposeful individuals—models that Weber called "ideal types"—from which actual historical events necessarily deviate due to accidental and irrational factors.[117] The analytical constructs of an ideal type never exist in reality, but provide objective benchmarks against which real-life constructs can be measured.[139]

{{quote|We know of no scientifically ascertainable ideals. To be sure, that makes our efforts more arduous than in the past, since we are expected to create our ideals from within our breast in the very age of subjectivist culture.|Max Weber, 1909[34]}}

Weber's methodology was developed in the context of a wider debate about methodology of social sciences, the Methodenstreit.[60] Weber's position was close to historicism, as he understood social actions as being heavily tied to particular historical contexts and its analysis required the understanding of subjective motivations of individuals (social actors).[60] Thus Weber's methodology emphasises the use of comparative historical analysis.[143] Therefore, Weber was more interested in explaining how a certain outcome was the result of various historical processes rather than predicting an outcome of those processes in the future.[125]

Rationalisation

Many scholars have described rationalisation and the question of individual freedom in an increasingly rational society, as the main theme of Weber's work.[8][146][147][148] This theme was situated in the larger context of the relationship between psychological motivations, cultural values and beliefs (primarily, religion) and the structure of the society (usually determined by the economy).[125]

By rationalisation, Weber understood first, the individual cost-benefit calculation, second, the wider bureaucratic organisation of the organisations and finally, in the more general sense as the opposite of understanding the reality through mystery and magic (disenchantment).[148]

{{quote|The fate of our times is characterised by rationalisation and intellectualisation and, above all, by the "disenchantment of the world"|Max Weber[151]}}

Weber began his studies of the subject in The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism, in which he argued that the redefinition of the connection between work and piety in Protestantism and especially in ascetic Protestant denominations, particularly Calvinism, shifted human effort towards rational efforts aimed at achieving economic gain.[152][153] In Protestant religion, Christian piety towards God was expressed through one's secular vocation (secularisation of calling).[153] The rational roots of this doctrine, he argued, soon grew incompatible with and larger than the religious and so the latter were eventually discarded.[155]

Weber continued his investigation into this matter in later works, notably in his studies on bureaucracy and on the classification of legitimate authority into three types—rational-legal, traditional and charismatic—of which the rational-legal (through bureaucracy) is the dominant one in the modern world.[8] In these works Weber described what he saw as society's movement towards rationalisation.[8] Similarly, rationalisation could be seen in the economy, with the development of highly rational and calculating capitalism.[8] Weber also saw rationalisation as one of the main factors setting the European West apart from the rest of the world.[8] Rationalisation relied on deep changes in ethics, religion, psychology and culture; changes that first took place in the Western civilisation.[8]

{{quote|What Weber depicted was not only the secularisation of Western culture, but also and especially the development of modern societies from the viewpoint of rationalisation. The new structures of society were marked by the differentiation of the two functionally intermeshing systems that had taken shape around the organisational cores of the capitalist enterprise and the bureaucratic state apparatus. Weber understood this process as the institutionalisation of purposive-rational economic and administrative action. To the degree that everyday life was affected by this cultural and societal rationalisation, traditional forms of life—which in the early modern period were differentiated primarily according to one's trade—were dissolved.|Jürgen Habermas|Modernity's Consciousness of Time, 1990 [1985][14]}}

Features of rationalisation include increasing knowledge, growing impersonality and enhanced control of social and material life.[8] Weber was ambivalent towards rationalisation; while admitting it was responsible for many advances, in particular, freeing humans from traditional, restrictive and illogical social guidelines, he also criticised it for dehumanising individuals as "cogs in the machine" and curtailing their freedom, trapping them in the bureaucratic iron cage of rationality and bureaucracy.[8][146][165][166] Related to rationalisation is the process of disenchantment, in which the world is becoming more explained and less mystical, moving from polytheistic religions to monotheistic ones and finally to the Godless science of modernity.[8] However, another interpretation of Weber's theory of disenchantment, advanced by historian of religion Jason Josephson-Storm, claims that Weber does not envision a binary between rationisation and magical thinking, and that Weber actually referred to the sequestering and professionalisation of magic when he described disenchantment, not to the disappearances of magic.[32]{{rp|299–300}} Regardless, for Weber the processes of rationalisation affect all of society, removing "sublime values ... from public life" and making art less creative.[169]

In a dystopian critique of rationalisation, Weber notes that modern society is a product of an individualistic drive of the Reformation, yet at the same time, the society created in this process is less and less welcoming of individualism.[8]

{{quote|How is it at all possible to salvage any remnants of "individual" freedom of movement in any sense given this all-powerful trend?|Max Weber[8]}}

Sociology of religion

Weber's work in the field of sociology of religion started with the essay The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism and continued with the analysis of Confucianism and Taoism, The Sociology of Hinduism and Buddhism and Ancient Judaism. His work on other religions was interrupted by his sudden death in 1920, which prevented him from following Ancient Judaism with studies of early Christianity and Islam.[172] His three main themes in the essays were the effect of religious ideas on economic activities, the relation between social stratification and religious ideas and the distinguishable characteristics of Western civilisation.[173]

Weber saw religion as one of the core forces in society.[143] His goal was to find reasons for the different development paths of the cultures of the Occident and the Orient, although without judging or valuing them, like some of the contemporary thinkers who followed the social Darwinist paradigm; Weber wanted primarily to explain the distinctive elements of the Western civilisation.[173] He maintained that Calvinist (and more widely, Protestant) religious ideas had a major impact on the social innovation and development of the economic system of the West, but noted that they were not the only factors in this development. Other notable factors mentioned by Weber included the rationalism of scientific pursuit, merging observation with mathematics, science of scholarship and jurisprudence, rational systematisation and bureaucratisation of government administration and economic enterprise.[173] In the end, the study of the sociology of religion, according to Weber, focused on one distinguishing part of the Western culture, the decline of beliefs in magic, or what he referred to as "disenchantment of the world".[173]

Weber also proposed a socioevolutionary model of religious change, showing that in general, societies have moved from magic to polytheism, then to pantheism, monotheism and finally, ethical monotheism.[178] According to Weber, this evolution occurred as the growing economic stability allowed professionalisation and the evolution of ever more sophisticated priesthood.[179] As societies grew more complex and encompassed different groups, a hierarchy of gods developed and as power in the society became more centralised, the concept of a single, universal God became more popular and desirable.[180]

The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism

{{Main|The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism}}

Weber's essay The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism is his most famous work.[71] It is argued{{By whom|date=October 2016}} that this work should not be viewed as a detailed study of Protestantism, but rather as an introduction into Weber's later works, especially his studies of interaction between various religious ideas and economic behaviour as part of the rationalisation of the economic system.[182] In The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism, Weber put forward the thesis that Calvinist ethic and ideas influenced the development of capitalism.[182] He noted the post-Reformation shift of Europe's economic centre away from Catholic countries such as France, Spain and Italy, and toward Protestant countries such as the Netherlands, England, Scotland and Germany. Weber also noted that societies having more Protestants were those with a more highly developed capitalist economy.[35] Similarly, in societies with different religions, most successful business leaders were Protestant.[182] Weber thus argued that Roman Catholicism impeded the development of the capitalist economy in the West, as did other religions such as Confucianism and Buddhism elsewhere in the world.[182]

{{quote|The development of the concept of the calling quickly gave to the modern entrepreneur a fabulously clear conscience—and also industrious workers; he gave to his employees as the wages of their ascetic devotion to the calling and of co-operation in his ruthless exploitation of them through capitalism the prospect of eternal salvation.|Max Weber[153]}}

Christian religious devotion had historically been accompanied by rejection of mundane affairs, including economic pursuit.[188] Weber showed that certain types of Protestantism—notably Calvinism—were supportive of rational pursuit of economic gain and worldly activities dedicated to it, seeing them as endowed with moral and spiritual significance.[152] Weber argued that there were many reasons to look for the origins of modern capitalism in the religious ideas of the Reformation.[190] In particular, the Protestant ethic (or more specifically, Calvinist ethic) motivated the believers to work hard, be successful in business and reinvest their profits in further development rather than frivolous pleasures.[182] The notion of calling meant that each individual had to take action as an indication of their salvation; just being a member of the Church was not enough.[153] Predestination also reduced agonising over economic inequality and further, it meant that a material wealth could be taken as a sign of salvation in the afterlife.[182][194] The believers thus justified pursuit of profit with religion, as instead of being fuelled by morally suspect greed or ambition, their actions were motivated by a highly moral and respected philosophy.[182] This Weber called the "spirit of capitalism": it was the Protestant religious ideology that was behind—and inevitably led to—the capitalist economic system.[182] This theory is often viewed as a reversal of Marx's thesis that the economic "base" of society determines all other aspects of it.[152]

Weber abandoned research into Protestantism because his colleague Ernst Troeltsch, a professional theologian, had begun work on the book The Social Teachings of the Christian Churches and Sects. Another reason for Weber's decision was that Troeltsch's work already achieved what he desired in that area: laying the groundwork for a comparative analysis of religion and society.[198]

The phrase "work ethic" used in modern commentary is a derivative of the "Protestant ethic" discussed by Weber. It was adopted when the idea of the Protestant ethic was generalised to apply to the Japanese people, Jews and other non-Christians and thus lost its religious connotations.[199]

The Religion of China: Confucianism and Taoism

{{Main|The Religion of China: Confucianism and Taoism}}The Religion of China: Confucianism and Taoism was Weber's second major work on the sociology of religion. Hans H. Gerth edited and translated this text into English, with an introduction by C. K. Wang.[36] Weber focused on those aspects of Chinese society that were different from those of Western Europe, especially those aspects that contrasted with Puritanism. His work also questioned why capitalism did not develop in China.[201] He focused on the issues of Chinese urban development, Chinese patrimonialism and officialdom and Chinese religion and philosophy (primarily, Confucianism and Taoism), as the areas in which Chinese development differed most distinctively from the European route.[201]

According to Weber, Confucianism and Puritanism are mutually exclusive types of rational thought, each attempting to prescribe a way of life based on religious dogma.[203] Notably, they both valued self-control and restraint and did not oppose accumulation of wealth.[203] However, to both those qualities were just means to the final goal and here they were divided by a key difference.[194] Confucianism's goal was "a cultured status position", while Puritanism's goal was to create individuals who are "tools of God".[203] The intensity of belief and enthusiasm for action were rare in Confucianism, but common in Protestantism.[203] Actively working for wealth was unbecoming a proper Confucian.[194] Therefore, Weber states that it was this difference in social attitudes and mentality, shaped by the respective, dominant religions, that contributed to the development of capitalism in the West and the absence of it in China.[203]

The Religion of India: The Sociology of Hinduism and Buddhism

{{Main|The Religion of India: The Sociology of Hinduism and Buddhism}}The Religion of India: The Sociology of Hinduism and Buddhism was Weber's third major work on the sociology of religion. In this work he deals with the structure of Indian society, with the orthodox doctrines of Hinduism and the heterodox doctrines of Buddhism, with modifications brought by the influence of popular religiosity and finally with the impact of religious beliefs on the secular ethic of Indian society.[210] In Weber's view, Hinduism in India, like Confucianism in China, was a barrier for capitalism.[194] The Indian caste system made it very difficult for individuals to advance in the society beyond their caste.[194] Activity, including economic activity, was seen as unimportant in the context of the advancement of the soul.[194]

Weber ended his research of society and religion in India by bringing in insights from his previous work on China to discuss similarities of the Asian belief systems.[214] He notes that the beliefs saw the meaning of life as otherworldly mystical experience.[214] The social world is fundamentally divided between the educated elite, following the guidance of a prophet or wise man and the uneducated masses whose beliefs are centered on magic.[214] In Asia, there was no Messianic prophecy to give plan and meaning to the everyday life of educated and uneducated alike.[214] Weber juxtaposed such Messianic prophecies (also called ethical prophecies), notably from the Near East region to the exemplary prophecies found on the Asiatic mainland, focused more on reaching to the educated elites and enlightening them on the proper ways to live one's life, usually with little emphasis on hard work and the material world.[214][219] It was those differences that prevented the countries of the Occident from following the paths of the earlier Chinese and Indian civilisations. His next work, Ancient Judaism was an attempt to prove this theory.[214]

Ancient Judaism

{{Main|Ancient Judaism (book)}}

In Ancient Judaism, his fourth major work on the sociology of religion, Weber attempted to explain the factors that resulted in the early differences between Oriental and Occidental religiosity.[221] He contrasted the innerworldly asceticism developed by Western Christianity with mystical contemplation of the kind developed in India.[221] Weber noted that some aspects of Christianity sought to conquer and change the world, rather than withdraw from its imperfections.[221] This fundamental characteristic of Christianity (when compared to Far Eastern religions) stems originally from ancient Jewish prophecy.[224]

Weber claimed that Judaism not only fathered Christianity and Islam, but was crucial to the rise of the modern Occidental state; Judaism's influence was as important as Hellenistic and Roman cultures.

Weber's death in 1920 prevented him from following his planned analysis of Psalms, the Book of Job, Talmudic Jewry, early Christianity and Islam.

Economy and Society

{{Main|Economy and Society}}

Weber's magnum opus Economy and Society is a collection of his essays that he was working on at the time of his death in 1920. After his death, the final organization and editing of the book fell to his widow Marianne Weber. The final German form published in 1921 reflected very much Marianne Weber's work and intellectual commitment. Beginning in 1956, the German jurist Johannes Wincklemann began editing and organizing the German edition of Economy and Society based on his study of the papers that Weber left at his death.

English versions of Economy and Society were published as a collected volume in 1968 as edited by Gunther Roth and Claus Wittich. As a result of the various editions in German and English, there are differences between the organization of the different volumes.

Economy and Society includes a wide range of essays dealing with Weber's views regarding Sociology, Social Philosophy, Politics, Social Stratification, World Religion, Diplomacy, and other subjects. The book is typically published in a two volume set in both German and English, and is more than 1000 pages long.

Theodicy of fortune and misfortune

The theodicy of fortune and misfortune within sociology is the theory, as Weber suggested, of how "members of different social classes adopt different belief systems, or theodices, to explain their social situation".[37]

The concept of theodicy was expanded mainly with the thought of Weber and his addition of ethical considerations to the subject of religion. There is this ethical part of religion, including, "...(1) soteriology and (2) theodicy. These mean, respectively, how people understand themselves to be capable of a correct relationship with supernatural powers, and how to explain evil—or why bad things seem to happen to those who seem to be good people."[38] There is a separation of different theodicies with regard to class. "Theodicies of misfortune tend to the belief that wealth and other manifestations of privilege are indications or signs of evil. ... In contrast, theodicies of fortune emphasise the notion that privileges are a blessing and are deserved."[38] Weber also writes that, "The affluent embrace good fortune theodicies, which emphasise that prosperity is a blessing of God ... [while] theodices of misfortune emphasise that affluence is a sign of evil and that suffering in this world will be rewarded in the next."[37] Thus these two distinctions can be applied not only to class structure within society but denomination and racial segregation within religion.

Weber defines the importance of societal class within religion by examining the difference between the two theodicies and to what class structures they apply. The concept of "work ethic" is attached to the theodicy of fortune; thus, because of the Protestant "work ethic", there was a contribution of higher class outcomes and more education among Protestants.[39] Those without the work ethic clung to the theodicy of misfortune, believing wealth and happiness were granted in the afterlife. Another example of how this belief of religious theodicy influences class, is that those of lower status, the poor, cling to deep religiousness and faith as a way to comfort themselves and provide hope for a more prosperous future, while those of higher status cling to the sacraments or actions that prove their right of possessing greater wealth.[37]

These two theodicies can be found in the denominational segregation within the religious community. The main division can be seen between the mainline Protestant and evangelical denominations and their relation to the class into which their particular theodicy pertains. For example, mainline churches, with their upper class congregations, "...promote[d] order, stability, and conservatism, and in so doing proved to be a powerful source of legitimation of the status quo and of existing disparities in the distribution of wealth and power," because much of the wealth of the church comes from the congregation.[40] In contrast, Pentecostal churches adopted the theodicy of misfortune. They instead "advocated change intended to advance the cause of justice and fairness".[40] Thus the learned and upper class religious churches who preach the theodicy of fortune, ultimately support capitalism and corporation, while the churches who adopted the theodicy of misfortune, instead preached equality and fairness.

Politics and government

{{see also|Weber and German politics}}

In political sociology, one of Weber's most influential contributions is his "Politics as a Vocation" (Politik als Beruf) essay. Therein, Weber unveils the definition of the state as that entity that possesses a monopoly on the legitimate use of physical force.[41][234][42] Weber wrote that politics is the sharing of state's power between various groups, and political leaders are those who wield this power.[234] A politician must not be a man of the "true Christian ethic", understood by Weber as being the ethic of the Sermon on the Mount, that is to say, the injunction to turn the other cheek.[237] An adherent of such an ethic ought rather to be understood as a saint, for it is only saints, according to Weber, that can appropriately follow it.[237] The political realm is no realm for saints; a politician ought to marry the ethic of attitude and the ethic of responsibility ("Verantwortungsethik vs Gesinnungsethik"[43]) and must possess both a passion for his vocation and the capacity to distance himself from the subject of his exertions (the governed).[237]

Weber distinguished three ideal types of political leadership (alternatively referred to as three types of domination, legitimisation or authority):[23][44]

  1. charismatic domination (familial and religious),
  2. traditional domination (patriarchs, patrimonialism, feudalism) and
  3. legal domination (modern law and state, bureaucracy).&91;243&93;

In his view, every historical relation between rulers and ruled contained such elements and they can be analysed on the basis of this tripartite distinction.[244] He notes that the instability of charismatic authority forces it to "routinise" into a more structured form of authority.[165] In a pure type of traditional rule, sufficient resistance to a ruler can lead to a "traditional revolution". The move towards a rational-legal structure of authority, utilising a bureaucratic structure, is inevitable in the end.[246] Thus this theory can be sometimes viewed as part of the social evolutionism theory. This ties to his broader concept of rationalisation by suggesting the inevitability of a move in this direction.[165]

{{quote|Bureaucratic administration means fundamentally domination through knowledge.|Max Weber[248]}}

Weber described many ideal types of public administration and government in his masterpiece Economy and Society (1922). His critical study of the bureaucratisation of society became one of the most enduring parts of his work.[165][248] It was Weber who began the studies of bureaucracy and whose works led to the popularisation of this term.[251] Many aspects of modern public administration go back to him and a classic, hierarchically organised civil service of the Continental type is called "Weberian civil service".[252] As the most efficient and rational way of organising, bureaucratisation for Weber was the key part of the rational-legal authority and furthermore, he saw it as the key process in the ongoing rationalisation of the Western society.[165][248]

Weber listed several preconditions for the emergence of the bureaucracy:[255] The growth in space and population being administered, the growth in complexity of the administrative tasks being carried out and the existence of a monetary economy—these resulted in a need for a more efficient administrative system.[255] Development of communication and transportation technologies made more efficient administration possible (and popularly requested) and democratisation and rationalisation of culture resulted in demands that the new system treat everybody equally.[255]

Weber's ideal bureaucracy is characterised by hierarchical organisation, by delineated lines of authority in a fixed area of activity, by action taken (and recorded) on the basis of written rules, by bureaucratic officials needing expert training, by rules being implemented neutrally and by career advancement depending on technical qualifications judged by organisations, not by individuals.[248][255]

{{quote|The decisive reason for the advance of the bureaucratic organisation has always been its purely technical superiority over any other form of organisation.|Max Weber[252]}}

While recognising bureaucracy as the most efficient form of organisation and even indispensable for the modern state, Weber also saw it as a threat to individual freedoms and the ongoing bureaucratisation as leading to a "polar night of icy darkness", in which increasing rationalisation of human life traps individuals in the aforementioned "iron cage" of bureaucratic, rule-based, rational control.[248][262] To counteract bureaucrats, the system needs entrepreneurs and politicians.[248]

Social stratification

Weber also formulated a three-component theory of stratification, with social class, social status and political party as conceptually distinct elements.[264] The three-component theory of stratification is in contrast to Karl Marx simpler theory of social class that ties all social stratification to what people own. In Weber's theory, issues of honour and prestige are important. This distinction is most clearly described in Weber's essay Classes, Staende, Parties, which was first published in his book Economy and Society.[45] The three components of Weber's theory are:

  • Social Class based on economically determined relationship to the market (owner, renter, employee, etc.)
  • Status (or in German Stand), which is based on non-economic qualities like honour, prestige and religion
  • Party, which refers to affiliations in the political domain

All three dimensions have consequences for what Weber called "life chances" (opportunities to improve one's life).[264]

Weber scholars maintain a sharp distinction between the terms status and class, even though, in casual use, people tend to use them interchangeably.[46]

Study of the city

As part of his overarching effort to understand the unique development of the Western world, Weber produced a detailed general study of the city as the characteristic locus of the social and economic relations, political arrangements, and ideas that eventually came to define the West. This resulted in a monograph, The City, which he probably compiled from research he conducted in 1911–13. It was published posthumously in 1921, and 1924, was incorporated into the second part of his Economy and Society, as chapter XVI, "The City (Non-legitimate Domination)".

According to Weber, the city as a politically autonomous organisation of people living in close proximity, employed in a variety of specialised trades, and physically separated from the surrounding countryside, only fully developed in the West and to a great extent shaped its cultural evolution:

{{quote|The origin of a rational and inner-worldly ethic is associated in the Occident with the appearance of thinkers and prophets ... who developed in a social context that was alien to the Asiatic cultures. This context consisted of the political problems engendered by the bourgeois status-group of the city, without which neither Judaism, nor Christianity, nor the development of Hellenistic thinking are conceivable.| Max Weber[47]}}

Weber argued that Judaism, early Christianity, theology, and later the political party and modern science, were only possible in the urban context that reached a full development in the West alone.[269] He also saw in the history of medieval European cities the rise of a unique form of "non-legitimate domination" that successfully challenged the existing forms of legitimate domination (traditional, charismatic, and rational-legal) that had prevailed until then in the Medieval world.[270] This new domination was based on the great economic and military power wielded by the organised community of city-dwellers ("citizens").

Economics

Weber regarded himself primarily as a "political economist",[271][272][273] and all of his professorial appointments were in economics, though today his contributions in that field are largely overshadowed by his role as a founder of modern sociology. As an economist, Weber belonged to the "youngest" German historical school of economics.[274] The great differences between that school's interests and methods on the one hand and those of the neoclassical school (from which modern mainstream economics largely derives) on the other, explain why Weber's influence on economics today is hard to discern.[48]

Methodological individualism

Though his research interests were always in line with those of the German historicists, with a strong emphasis on interpreting economic history, Weber's defence of "methodological individualism" in the social sciences represented an important break with that school and an embracing of many of the arguments that had been made against the historicists by Carl Menger, the founder of the Austrian School of economics, in the context of the academic Methodenstreit ("debate over methods") of the late 19th century.[117] The phrase methodological individualism, which has come into common usage in modern debates about the connection between microeconomics and macroeconomics, was coined by the Austrian-American economist Joseph Schumpeter in 1908 as a way of referring to the views of Weber.[117] According to Weber's theses, social research cannot be fully inductive or descriptive, because understanding some phenomenon implies that the researcher must go beyond mere description and interpret it; interpretation requires classification according to abstract "ideal (pure) types".[274] This, together with his antipositivistic argumentation (see Verstehen), can be taken as a methodological justification for the model of the "rational economic man" (homo economicus), which is at the heart of modern mainstream economics.[117][274]

Marginalism and psychophysics

Unlike other historicists, Weber also accepted the marginal theory of value (also called "marginalism") and taught it to his students.[116][282] In 1908, Weber published an article in which he drew a sharp methodological distinction between psychology and economics and attacked the claims that the marginal theory of value in economics reflected the form of the psychological response to stimuli as described by the Weber-Fechner law. Max Weber's article has been cited as a definitive refutation of the dependence of the economic theory of value on the laws of psychophysics by Lionel Robbins, George Stigler,[49] and Friedrich Hayek, though the broader issue of the relation between economics and psychology has come back into the academic debate with the development of "behavioral economics".[50]

Economic history

Weber's best known work in economics concerned the preconditions for capitalist development, particularly the relations between religion and capitalism, which he explored in The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism as well as in his other works on the sociology of religion.[274] He argued that bureaucratic political and economic systems emerging in the Middle Ages were essential in the rise of modern capitalism (including rational book-keeping and organisation of formally free labour), while they were a hindrance in the case of ancient capitalism, which had a different social and political structure based on conquest, slavery, and the coastal city-state.[51] Other contributions include his early work on the economic history of Roman agrarian society (1891) and on the labour relations in Eastern Germany (1892), his analysis of the history of commercial partnerships in the Middle Ages (1889), his critique of Marxism, the discussion of the roles of idealism and materialism in the history of capitalism in his Economy and Society (1922) and his General Economic History (1923), a notable example of the kind of empirical work associated with the German Historical School.[274]

Although today Weber is primarily read by sociologists and social philosophers, Weber's work did have a significant influence on Frank Knight, one of the founders of the neoclassical Chicago school of economics, who translated Weber's General Economic History into English in 1927.[288] Knight also wrote in 1956 that Max Weber was the only economist who dealt with the problem of understanding the emergence of modern capitalism "...from the angle which alone can yield an answer to such questions, that is, the angle of comparative history in the broad sense."[282]

Economic calculation

Weber, like his colleague Werner Sombart, regarded economic calculation and especially the double-entry bookkeeping method of business accounting, as one of the most important forms of rationalisation associated with the development of modern capitalism.[290] Weber's preoccupation with the importance of economic calculation led him to critique socialism as a system that lacked a mechanism for allocating resources efficiently to satisfy human needs.[291] Socialist intellectuals like Otto Neurath had realised that in a completely socialised economy, prices would not exist and central planners would have to resort to in-kind (rather than monetary) economic calculation.[291][293] According to Weber, this type of coordination would be inefficient, especially because it would be incapable of solving the problem of imputation (i.e. of accurately determining the relative values of capital goods).[291][293] Weber wrote that, under full socialism,

{{quote|In order to make possible a rational utilisation of the means of production, a system of in-kind accounting would have to determine "value"—indicators of some kind for the individual capital goods which could take over the role of the "prices" used in book valuation in modern business accounting. But it is not at all clear how such indicators could be established and in particular, verified; whether, for instance, they should vary from one production unit to the next (on the basis of economic location), or whether they should be uniform for the entire economy, on the basis of "social utility", that is, of (present and future) consumption requirements ... Nothing is gained by assuming that, if only the problem of a non-monetary economy were seriously enough attacked, a suitable accounting method would be discovered or invented. The problem is fundamental to any kind of complete socialisation. We cannot speak of a rational "planned economy" so long as in this decisive respect we have no instrument for elaborating a rational "plan".|Max Weber[296]}}

This argument against socialism was made independently, at about the same time, by Ludwig von Mises.[291][298] Weber himself had a significant influence on Mises, whom he had befriended when they were both at the University of Vienna in the spring of 1918,[299] and, through Mises, on several other economists associated with the Austrian School in the 20th century.[300] Friedrich Hayek in particular elaborated the arguments of Weber and Mises about economic calculation into a central part of free market economics's intellectual assault on socialism, as well as into a model for the spontaneous coordination of "dispersed knowledge" in markets.[52][53][303]

Legacy

{{quote|The prestige of Max Weber among European social scientists would be difficult to over-estimate. He is widely considered the greatest of German sociologists and ... has become a leading influence in European and American thought.| Hans Heinrich Gerth and C. Wright Mills, From Max Weber: Essays in Sociology, 1946/1991[9]}}

Weber's most influential work was on economic sociology, political sociology, and the sociology of religion. Along with Karl Marx and Émile Durkheim,[272] he is commonly regarded as one of the founders of modern sociology. But whereas Durkheim, following Comte, worked in the positivist tradition, Weber was instrumental in developing an antipositivist, hermeneutic, tradition in the social sciences.[306] In this regard he belongs to a similar tradition as his German colleagues Werner Sombart, Georg Simmel, and Wilhelm Dilthey, who stressed the differences between the methodologies appropriate to the social and the natural sciences.[306]

Weber presented sociology as the science of human social action; action that he separated into traditional, affectional, value-rational and instrumental.[308][309]

{{quote|[Sociology is] the science whose object is to interpret the meaning of social action and thereby give a causal explanation of the way in which the action proceeds and the effects which it produces. By "action" in this definition is meant the human behaviour when and to the extent that the agent or agents see it as subjectively meaningful ... the meaning to which we refer may be either (a) the meaning actually intended either by an individual agent on a particular historical occasion or by a number of agents on an approximate average in a given set of cases, or (b) the meaning attributed to the agent or agents, as types, in a pure type constructed in the abstract. In neither case is the "meaning" to be thought of as somehow objectively "correct" or "true" by some metaphysical criterion. This is the difference between the empirical sciences of action, such as sociology and history and any kind of a priori discipline, such as jurisprudence, logic, ethics, or aesthetics whose aim is to extract from their subject-matter "correct" or "valid" meaning.[54]|Max Weber, The Nature of Social Action, 1922}}

In his own time, however, Weber was viewed primarily as a historian and an economist.[272][273] The breadth of Weber's topical interests is apparent in the depth of his social theory:

{{quote|The affinity between capitalism and Protestantism, the religious origins of the Western world, the force of charisma in religion as well as in politics, the all-embracing process of rationalisation and the bureaucratic price of progress, the role of legitimacy and of violence as the offspring of leadership, the "disenchantment" of the modern world together with the never-ending power of religion, the antagonistic relation between intellectualism and eroticism: all these are key concepts which attest to the enduring fascination of Weber's thinking.| Joachim Radkau, Max Weber: A Biography, 2005[55]}}

Many of Weber's works famous today were collected, revised and published posthumously. Significant interpretations of his writings were produced by such sociological luminaries as Talcott Parsons and C. Wright Mills. Parsons in particular imparted to Weber's works a functionalist, teleological perspective; this personal interpretation has been criticised for a latent conservatism.[56]

Weber has influenced many later social theorists, such as Theodor Adorno, Max Horkheimer, György Lukács and Jürgen Habermas.[8] Different elements of his thought were emphasised by Carl Schmitt, Joseph Schumpeter, Ludwig Lachmann, Leo Strauss, Hans Morgenthau, and Raymond Aron.[8] According to Austrian economist Ludwig von Mises, who had met Weber during his time at the University of Vienna,

{{quote|The early death of this genius was a great disaster for Germany. Had Weber lived longer, the German people of today would be able to look to this example of an "Aryan" who would not be broken by National Socialism.|Ludwig von Mises, 1940[57]}}

Weber's friend, the psychiatrist and existentialist philosopher Karl Jaspers, described him as "the greatest German of our era". Weber's untimely death felt to Jaspers "as if the German world had lost its heart".[58] Paul Tillich, University Professor at Harvard, observed about Weber that he was "perhaps the greatest scholar in Germany of the nineteenth century". (Paul Tillich, "A History of Christian Thought", 1968, p. 233)

Critical responses to Weber

Weber's explanations are highly specific to the historical periods he analysed.[319] Some academics disagree, pointing out that, despite the fact that Weber did write in the early twentieth century, his ideas remain alive and relevant for understanding issues like politics, bureaucracy, and social stratification today.{{Sfn | Waters | Waters | 2015 | pp = 1–18}}

Many scholars, however, disagree with specific claims in Weber's historical analysis. For example, the economist Joseph Schumpeter argued that capitalism did not begin with the Industrial Revolution but in 14th century Italy.[59] In Milan, Venice and Florence, the small city-state governments led to the development of the earliest forms of capitalism.[60] In the 16th century, Antwerp was a commercial centre of Europe. Also, the predominantly Calvinist country of Scotland did not enjoy the same economic growth as the Netherlands, England and New England. It has been pointed out that the Netherlands, which had a Calvinist majority, industrialised much later in the 19th century than predominantly Catholic Belgium, which was one of the centres of the Industrial Revolution on the European mainland.[61] Emil Kauder expanded Schumpeter's argument, by arguing the hypothesis that Calvinism hurt the development of capitalism by leading to the development of the labour theory of value.[62]

Works

For an extensive list of Max Weber's works, see Max Weber bibliography.

Weber wrote in German. Original titles printed after his death (1920) are most likely compilations of his unfinished works (of the Collected Essays ... form). Many translations are made of parts or sections of various German originals and the names of the translations often do not reveal what part of German work they contain. Weber's work is generally quoted according to the critical [https://www.mohr.de/en/multi-volume-work/max-weber-gesamtausgabe-323700000 Max Weber-Gesamtausgabe] (Collected Works edition), which is published by Mohr Siebeck in Tübingen.

See also

{{portal|Sociology|Max Weber}}
  • Interpretations of Weber's liberalism
  • Instrumental and value-rational action
  • Robert Michels
  • Sociology of law
  • Speeches of Max Weber
  • Weber and German politics
  • Werturteilsstreit

References

1. ^{{Citation | last = Bellamy | first = Richard | title = Liberalism and Modern Society | publisher = Polity | year = 1992 | page = 165}}.
2. ^{{cite book |last1=Najemy |first1=John M. |title=The Cambridge Companion to Machiavelli |date=2010 |publisher=Cambridge University Press |page=259}}
3. ^{{cite book |last1=Mommsen |first1=Wolfgang J. |title=Max Weber and His Contempories |date=2013 |publisher=Routledge |pages=8–10}}
4. ^{{Citation | first1 = Reinhard | last1 = Bendix | author1-link = Reinhard Bendix | first2 = Guenther | last2 = Roth | author2-link = Guenther Roth | url = https://books.google.com/books?id=ottM0fiTnO8C | title = Scholarship and Partisanship: Essays on Max Weber | publisher = University of California Press | year = 1971 | page = 244| isbn = 978-0520041714 }}.
5. ^"Weber". Random House Webster's Unabridged Dictionary.
6. ^{{Citation | contribution = Max Weber | title = Encyclopædia Britannica | edition = online | date = 20 April 2009 | contribution-url = http://www.britannica.com/EBchecked/topic/638565/Max-Weber}}.
7. ^Radkau, Joachim and Patrick Camiller (2009). Max Weber: A Biography. Trans. Patrick Camiller. Polity Press. {{ISBN|978-0-74564147-8}}.
8. ^{{cite book |title=Capitalism and Modern Social Theory: an Analysis of the Writings of Marx, Durkheim and Max Weber |last=Giddens |first=Anthony |year= 1971 |publisher= Cambridge University Press |isbn= 978-0-52109785-7}}
9. ^Auguste Comte, Marx and Weber: {{cite book |title= Philosophical Foundations of the Three Sociologies |last=Benton |first= Ted |year=1977 |publisher= Rout-ledge & Kegan Paul |location= London |isbn=978-0-71008593-1}}
10. ^{{cite book |title=For Durkheim: Essays in Historical and Cultural Sociology |last=Tiryakian |first=Edward A. |year= 2009 |publisher= Routledge |isbn= 978-0-75467155-8 |page=321}}
11. ^{{cite book |title= Sociology | edition = 14th |last= Macionis |first=John J. |year=2012 |publisher= Pearson |location=Boston |isbn= 978-0-205-11671-3 |page=88}}
12. ^Weber, Max The Protestant Ethic and "The Spirit of Capitalism" (1905). Transl. by Stephen Kalberg (2002), Roxbury Publ. Co., pp. 19, 35; Weber's references on these pages to "Superstructure" and "base" are unambiguous references to Marxism's base/superstructure theory.
13. ^Sica, Alan (2004). Max Weber and the New Century. London: Transaction Publishers, p. 24. {{ISBN|0-7658-0190-6}}.
14. ^{{Citation | last = McKinnon | first = AM | year = 2010 | title = Elective affinities of the Protestant ethic: Weber and the chemistry of capitalism | journal = Sociological Theory | volume = 28 | number = 1 | pages = 108–26 | url = http://aura.abdn.ac.uk/bitstream/2164/3035/1/McKinnon_Elective_Affinities_final_non_format.pdf | doi=10.1111/j.1467-9558.2009.01367.x}}.
15. ^Weber, Max. Political Writings. Cambridge University Press, 1994, p. ix.
16. ^Weber, Max. Political Writings. University of Cambridge Press, 1994. pp. 1–28.
17. ^{{cite journal|url=http://www.newyorker.com/archive/2004/11/29/041129crbo_books|title=Why Work? |journal=The New Yorker|accessdate=25 September 2014|date=2004-11-22}}
18. ^{{cite journal |last=Iannaccone |first=Laurence |year=1998 |title=Introduction to the Economics of Religion |journal=Journal of Economic Literature |volume=36 |issue=3 |pages=1465–96 |jstor=2564806 }}
19. ^Michael Wise, "Max Weber Visits America: A Review of the Video," Sociation Today, volume 4, number 2, Fall 2006.
20. ^{{Citation | last1 = Gerth | first1 = H.H | first2 = C. Wright | last2 = Mills | author2-link = C. Wright Mills | year = 1948 | title = From Max Weber: Essays in Sociology | place = London | publisher = Routledge | isbn = 978-0-415-17503-6}}.
21. ^Sven Eliaeson, "Constitutional Caesarism: Weber's Politics in their German Context", in Turner, Stephen (ed) (2000). The Cambridge Companion to Weber. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, [https://books.google.com/books?vid=ISBN052156753X&id=XfGZ3ivPR4cC&pg=PA142 p. 142.]
22. ^{{Citation | page = 209 | title = Max Weber, A Biography | first = Joachim | last = Radkau | place = New York | publisher = Polity Press | year = 2009}}.
23. ^Jeong Chun Hai @Ibrahim, & Nor Fadzlina Nawi. (2012). Principles of Public Administration: Malaysian Perspectives. Kuala Lumpur: Pearson Publishers. {{ISBN|978-967-349-233-6}}
24. ^Weber 2015:76, in Weber's Rationalism and Modern Society, Edited and Translated by Tony Waters and Dagmar Waters, New York: Palgrave Macmillan
25. ^Weber 2015:76 in Weber's Rationalism and Modern Society, Edited and Translated by Tony Waters and Dagmar Waters, New York: Palgrave Macmillan
26. ^Weber 2015:76–77 in Weber's Rationalism and Modern Society, Edited and Translated by Tony Waters and Dagmar Waters, New York: Palgrave Macmillan
27. ^James W. Fesler. (1965). "Bureaucratic Phenomena". Administrative Science Quarterly, Volume 10, September 1965, p. 163.
28. ^{{cite book |first=David |last=Frisby |title=Georg Simmel |series=Key Sociologists |edition=Second |publisher=Routledge |location=London |year=2002 |isbn=978-0-415-28535-3 }}
29. ^Weber, Max. Political Writings. Cambridge University Press, 1994, p. 288.
30. ^H.H. Gerth and C.W. Mills, [https://books.google.com/books?id=Y_pqZS5q72UC&pg=PA25 "A Biographical View"] in From Max Weber: Essays in Sociology.
31. ^{{cite journal |first=Alan |last=Mittleman |doi=10.1006/reli.1999.0176 |title=Leo Strauss and Relativism: the Critique of Max Weber |journal=Religion |volume=29 |issue= |pages=15–27 |year=1999 }}
32. ^{{Cite book | last = Josephson-Storm | first = Jason | title = The Myth of Disenchantment: Magic, Modernity, and the Birth of the Human Sciences | publisher = University of Chicago Press | date = 2017 | url = https://books.google.com/books?id=xZ5yDgAAQBAJ | isbn = 978-0-226-40336-6 }}
33. ^Max Weber, Sociological Writings, Excerpts
34. ^Quoted in Roth, Guenther and Claus Wittich. 1978. Economy and Society: an outline of interpretive sociology. University of California Press, [https://books.google.com/books?hl=en&lr=&id=pSdaNuIaUUEC&oi=fnd&pg=PR25&dq=Economy+Society+Weber&ots=Up5aqLGHvp&sig=J6WB3OKaxTo2kpBXzjeFvnp9xNs#PPR33,M1 Google Print, p. xxxiii]
35. ^Weber The Protestant Ethic ... , pp. 15–16
36. ^Max Weber, The Religion of China, New York: Free Press, 1968.
37. ^{{cite web|last=Plye, Davidson|first=Ralph, James|title=Stratification|url=http://hirr.hartsem.edu/ency/stratification.htm|publisher=Encyclopedia of Religion and Society|accessdate=27 May 2012}}
38. ^{{cite book|last=Christiano, Swatos, Kivisto|first=Kevin, William, Peter|title=Sociology of Religion|year=2008|publisher=Rowman & Littlefield Publishers Inc|location=New York|isbn=978-0742561113|page=7}}
39. ^{{cite book|last=Christiano, Swatos, Kivisto|first=Kevin, William, Peter|title=Sociology of Religion|year=2008|publisher=Rowman & Littlefield Publishers Inc|location=New York|isbn=978-0742561113|page=142}}
40. ^{{cite book|last=Christiano, Swatos, Kivisto|first=Kevin, William, Peter|title=Sociology of Religion|year=2008|publisher=Rowman & Littlefield Publishers Inc|location=New York|isbn=978-0742561113|page=137}}
41. ^Weber, Max (1919/2015) "Politics as Vocation" in Weber's Rationalism and Modern Society,edited and translated by Tony Waters and Dagmar Waters, pp. 129–98
42. ^{{cite journal|last1=Phelps|first1=Martha Lizabeth|title=Doppelgangers of the State: Private Security and Transferable Legitimacy|journal=Politics & Policy|date=December 2014|volume=42|issue=6|pages=824–49|doi=10.1111/polp.12100}}
43. ^Politik als Beruf – Gesinnungsethik vs. Verantwortungsethik (1919)
44. ^pp. 135–36 in "Politics as Vocation" by Max Weber in Weber's Rationalism and Modern Society, edited and translated by Tony Waters and Dagmar Waters. New York: Palgrave MacMillan 21919/2015
45. ^Max Weber, "The Distribution of Power Within the Gemeinschaft: Classes, Staende, Parties" pp. 59–72 in Weber's Rationalism and Modern Society, edited and translated by Tony Waters and Dagmar Waters.
46. ^Waters, Tony (2016). "Are the terms "socio-economic status" and "class status" a warped form of reasoning for Max Weber? Palgrave Communications. http://www.palgrave-journals.com/articles/palcomms20162
47. ^Quoted in {{cite book |last=Bendix |first=Reinhard |authorlink=Reinhard Bendix |title=Max Weber: An Intellectual Portrait |url= https://books.google.com/?id=63sC9uaYqQsC&pg=PA1&lpg=PA79 |year= 1977 |publisher= University of California Press |isbn= 978-0-520-03194-4 |page= 79}}
48. ^"The German Historical School" {{webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20110220030838/http://homepage.newschool.edu/~het/schools/historic.htm |date=20 February 2011 }}, New School for Social Research
49. ^{{cite journal | last1 = Stigler | first1 = George | year = 1950 | title = The Development of Utility Theory | journal = The Journal of Political Economy | volume = 58 | issue = 5| pages = 373–96 | jstor=1825710 | doi=10.1086/256980}}
50. ^{{cite journal | last1 = Mass | first1 = Harro | year = 2009 | title = Disciplining Boundaries: Lionel Robbins, Max Weber, and the Borderlands of Economics, History, and Psychology | url = http://journals.cambridge.org/action/displayAbstract?fromPage=online&aid=6773500 | journal = Journal of the History of Economic Thought | volume = 31 | issue = 4| page = 500 | doi = 10.1017/S1053837209990289 }}
51. ^Weber, Max. Selections in Translation. Trans. Eric Matthews. Ed. W.G. Runciman. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. "Urbanisation and Social Structure in the Ancient World", pp. 290–314.
52. ^Friedrich Hayek, "[https://mises.org/daily/4590/media.aspx?action=author&ID=425 Socialist Calculation]", in Individualism and Economic Order, (University of Chicago Press, 1948).
53. ^Interview with F.A. Hayek, 1985
54. ^Weber, Max The Nature of Social Action, in Runciman, W.G., Weber: Selections in Translation, Cambridge University Press, 1991. p. 7.
55. ^Radkau, Joachim Max Weber: A Biography. 1995. Polity Press. (Inside sleeve)
56. ^Fish, Jonathan S. 2005. Defending the Durkheimian Tradition. Religion, Emotion and Morality Aldershot: Ashgate Publishing.
57. ^Ludwig von Mises, [https://mises.org/books/memoirs_mises.pdf Memoirs], (Mises Institute, Auburn, AL, 2009), p. 88.
58. ^Quoted in Peter Baehr, "[https://books.google.com/books?id=uN__U6VdHEgC&pg=PA410 The Grammar of Prudence: Arendt, Jaspers and the Appraisal of Max Weber]", in Hannah Arendt in Jerusalem, edited by Steven E. Aschheim (University of California Press, 2001), p. 410.
59. ^{{cite book |last= Schumpeter |first=Joseph |title= History of Economic Analysis | publisher= Oxford University Press |year= 1954}}
60. ^{{cite book |last= Rothbard |first=Murray N. |title= Economic Thought Before Adam Smith | publisher= Ludwig von Mises Press |year= 1995 |page=142}}
61. ^{{cite book |last= Evans |first= Eric J. |title= The Forging of the Modern State: Early Industrial Britain, 1783–1870 | publisher= Longman |year=1983 |page= 114 |isbn=978-0-582-48969-1}}
62. ^{{cite journal |last= Kauder |first=Emil |title= The Retarded Acceptance of the Marginal Utility Theory |journal=Quarterly Journal of Economics |volume=67 |issue= 4 |pages=564–75 |year=1953 |jstor= 1883602 |doi= 10.2307/1883602}}
63. ^{{cite book | first1 =Kenneth D. | last1 = Allan |title= Explorations in Classical Sociological Theory: Seeing the Social World |date=2005 |publisher= Pine Forge Press |isbn= 978-1-4129-0572-5 |page= 146}}
64. ^{{cite book | first1 =Kenneth D. | last1 = Allan |title=Explorations in Classical Sociological Theory: Seeing the Social World|date=2005|publisher=Pine Forge Press|isbn=978-1-4129-0572-5|page=148}}
65. ^{{cite book| first1 =Kenneth D. | last1 = Allan |title=Explorations in Classical Sociological Theory: Seeing the Social World|date=2005|publisher=Pine Forge Press|isbn=978-1-4129-0572-5|page=149}}
66. ^{{cite book| first1 =Kenneth D. | last1 = Allan |title=Explorations in Classical Sociological Theory: Seeing the Social World|date=2005|publisher=Pine Forge Press|isbn=978-1-4129-0572-5|pages=150–51}}
67. ^{{cite book| first1 =Kenneth D. | last1 = Allan |title=Explorations in Classical Sociological Theory: Seeing the Social World|date=2005|publisher=Pine Forge Press|isbn=978-1-4129-0572-5|page=151}}
68. ^{{cite book| first1 =Kenneth D. | last1 = Allan |title=Explorations in Classical Sociological Theory: Seeing the Social World|date=2005|publisher=Pine Forge Press|isbn=978-1-4129-0572-5|pages=151–52}}
69. ^{{cite book| first1 =Kenneth D. | last1 = Allan |title=Explorations in Classical Sociological Theory: Seeing the Social World|date=2005|publisher=Pine Forge Press|isbn=978-1-4129-0572-5|page=153}}
70. ^{{cite book| first1 =Kenneth D. | last1 = Allan |title=Explorations in Classical Sociological Theory: Seeing the Social World|date=2005|publisher=Pine Forge Press|isbn=978-1-4129-0572-5|page=154}}
71. ^{{cite book| first1 =Kenneth D. | last1 = Allan |title=Explorations in Classical Sociological Theory: Seeing the Social World|date=2005|publisher=Pine Forge Press|isbn=978-1-4129-0572-5|page=155}}
72. ^{{cite book| first1 =Kenneth D. | last1 = Allan |title=Explorations in Classical Sociological Theory: Seeing the Social World|date= 2005|publisher=Pine Forge Press|isbn=978-1-4129-0572-5|page=158}}
73. ^{{cite book| first1 =Kenneth D. | last1 = Allan |title=Explorations in Classical Sociological Theory: Seeing the Social World|date=2005|publisher=Pine Forge Press|isbn=978-1-4129-0572-5|page=162}}
74. ^{{cite book| first1 =Kenneth D. | last1 = Allan |title=Explorations in Classical Sociological Theory: Seeing the Social World|date=2005|publisher=Pine Forge Press|isbn=978-1-4129-0572-5|pages=172–76}}
75. ^{{cite book| first1 =Kenneth D. | last1 = Allan |title=Explorations in Classical Sociological Theory: Seeing the Social World|date=2005|publisher=Pine Forge Press|isbn=978-1-4129-0572-5|page=177}}
76. ^{{cite book|author=Andrew J. Weigert|title=Mixed emotions: certain steps toward understanding ambivalence|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=uH0srBp2W4YC&pg=PA110|accessdate=22 March 2011|date=1991|publisher=SUNY Press|isbn=978-0-7914-0600-7|page=110}}
77. ^{{cite book |last=Bendix |first=Reinhard |authorlink=Reinhard Bendix |title=Max Weber: An Intellectual Portrait |url=https://books.google.com/?id=63sC9uaYqQsC&pg=PA1&lpg=PA1 |publisher=University of California Press |isbn=978-0-520-03194-4 |page=1 |year=1977 }}
78. ^{{cite book |last=Bendix |title=Max Weber |url=https://books.google.com/?id=63sC9uaYqQsC&pg=PA135&lpg=PA135|pages=135–41 |isbn=978-0-520-03194-4 |year=1977}}
79. ^{{cite book |last=Bendix |title=Max Weber |url=https://books.google.com/?id=63sC9uaYqQsC&pg=PA142&lpg=PA142 |pages=142–58 |isbn=978-0-520-03194-4 |year=1977}}
80. ^{{cite book |last=Bendix |title=Max Weber |url=https://books.google.com/?id=63sC9uaYqQsC&pg=PA199&lpg=PA199 |page=199 |isbn=978-0-520-03194-4 |year=1977}}
81. ^{{cite book |last=Bendix |title=Max Weber |url=https://books.google.com/?id=63sC9uaYqQsC&pg=PA2&lpg=PA2 |page=2 |isbn=978-0-520-03194-4 |year=1977 }}
82. ^{{cite book |last=Bendix |title=Max Weber |url=https://books.google.com/?id=63sC9uaYqQsC&pg=PA200&lpg=PA200 |pages=200–01 |isbn=978-0-520-03194-4 |year=1977}}
83. ^{{cite book |last=Bendix |title=Max Weber |url=https://books.google.com/?id=63sC9uaYqQsC&pg=PA204&lpg=PA204 |pages=204–05 |isbn=978-0-520-03194-4 |year=1977}}
84. ^{{cite book |last=Bendix |title=Max Weber |url=https://books.google.com/?id=63sC9uaYqQsC&pg=PA285&lpg=PA285 |page=285 |isbn=978-0-520-03194-4 |year=1977 }}
85. ^{{cite book |last=Bendix |title=Max Weber|url=https://books.google.com/?id=63sC9uaYqQsC&pg=PA296&lpg=PA296|page=296 |isbn=978-0-520-03194-4 |year=1977}}
86. ^{{cite book |last=Bendix |title=Max Weber |url=https://books.google.com/?id=63sC9uaYqQsC&pg=PA3&lpg=PA2 |page=3 |isbn=978-0-520-03194-4 |year=1977 }}
87. ^{{cite book |last=Bendix |title=Max Weber|url=https://books.google.com/?id=C_j_2nOUIpcC&pg=PA303&lpg=PA303|pages=303–05 |isbn=978-0-415-17453-4 |date=1998}}
88. ^{{cite book |last=Bendix |title=Max Weber |url=https://books.google.com/?id=63sC9uaYqQsC&pg=PA49&lpg=PA49 |page=49 |isbn=978-0-520-03194-4 |year=1977}}
89. ^{{cite book |last=Bendix |title=Max Weber |url=|page=54}}
90. ^{{cite book |last=Bendix |title=Max Weber |url=https://books.google.com/?id=63sC9uaYqQsC&pg=PA57&lpg=PA57&vq=mundane+affairs|page=57 |isbn=978-0-520-03194-4 |year=1977}}
91. ^{{cite book |last=Bendix |title=Max Weber |url=https://books.google.com/?id=63sC9uaYqQsC&pg=PA60&lpg=PA60&vq=Calvinism |pages=60–61 |isbn=978-0-520-03194-4 |year=1977 }}
92. ^{{cite book |last=Bendix |title=Max Weber |url=https://books.google.com/?id=63sC9uaYqQsC&pg=PA85&lpg=PA85 |pages=85–87 |isbn=978-0-520-03194-4 |year=1977}}
93. ^{{cite book|author=Reinhard Bendix|title=Max Weber: an intellectual portrait|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=65IUL-VaFGsC&pg=PA90|accessdate=5 April 2011|year=1977|publisher=University of California Press|isbn=978-0-520-03194-4|page=90}}
94. ^{{cite book |last=Bendix |title=Max Weber |url=https://books.google.com/?id=63sC9uaYqQsC&pg=PA98&lpg=PA98 |pages=98–99 |isbn=978-0-520-03194-4 |year=1977}}
95. ^{{cite book |last=Bendix |title=Max Weber |chapter-url=https://books.google.com/?id=63sC9uaYqQsC&pg=PA285&lpg=PA285 |chapter=IX: Basic Concepts of Political Sociology |nopp=true |isbn=978-0-520-03194-4 |year=1977 }}
96. ^{{cite book|author1=Marshall Sashkin|author2=Molly G. Sashkin|title=Leadership that matters: the critical factors for making a difference in people's lives and organisations' success|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=q12zbgs-jyYC&pg=PA52|accessdate=22 March 2011|date=2003|publisher=Berrett-Koehler Publishers|isbn=978-1-57675-193-0|page=52}}
97. ^{{cite book|author1=Richard Swedberg|author2=Ola Agevall|title=The Max Weber dictionary: key words and central concepts|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=_c3Mcnh8hCgC&pg=PA19|accessdate=23 March 2011|year=2005|publisher=Stanford University Press|isbn=978-0-8047-5095-0|pages=18–21}}
98. ^{{cite book|author=Craig J. Calhoun|title=Classical sociological theory|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=6mq-H3EcUx8C&pg=PA165|accessdate=19 March 2011|year=2002|publisher=Wiley-Blackwell|isbn=978-0-631-21348-2|page=165}}
99. ^{{cite book|author=Craig J. Calhoun|title=Classical sociological theory|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=6mq-H3EcUx8C&pg=PA166|accessdate=19 March 2011|year=2002|publisher=Wiley-Blackwell|isbn=978-0-631-21348-2|page=166}}
100. ^{{cite book|author=Craig J. Calhoun|title=Classical sociological theory|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=6mq-H3EcUx8C&pg=PA166|accessdate=19 March 2011|year=2002|publisher=Wiley-Blackwell|isbn=978-0-631-21348-2|page=167}}
101. ^{{cite book|author=Robert B. Denhardt|title=Theories of Public Organization|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=0mt5MF9EBJgC&pg=PA27|accessdate=14 April 2011|date=2010|publisher=Cengage Learning|isbn=978-1-4390-8623-0|page=27}}
102. ^{{cite book|author=Daniel Warner|title=An ethic of responsibility in international relations|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=jNc4mc_MYdIC&pg=PA9|accessdate=5 April 2011|year=1991|publisher=Lynne Rienner Publishers|isbn=978-1-55587-266-3|pages=9–10}}
103. ^{{cite book|author1=Max Weber|author2=Richard Swedberg|title=Essays in economic sociology|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=WaV7Q35jy_AC&pg=PA22|accessdate=22 March 2011|year=1999|publisher=Princeton University Press|isbn=978-0-691-00906-3|page=22}}
104. ^{{cite book|author1=Max Weber|author2=Richard Swedberg|title=Essays in economic sociology|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=WaV7Q35jy_AC&pg=PA7|accessdate=22 March 2011|year=1999|publisher=Princeton University Press|isbn=978-0-691-00906-3|page=7}}
105. ^Max Weber, [https://books.google.com/books?id=pSdaNuIaUUEC Economy and Society: An Outline of Interpretive Sociology], Guenther Roth and Claus Wittich, eds. (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1978), vol. I, ch. 2., sec. 12, pp. 100–03.
106. ^{{cite book|author1=Ross B. Emmett|title=Frank Knight and the Chicago School in American Economics|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=h0iLWOEln-EC&pg=PA111|accessdate=1 April 2011|year=2005|publisher=Routledge|isbn=9780415775007|pages=111–23}}
107. ^Joan Ferrante, Sociology: A Global Perspective, Thomson Wadsworth, 2005, {{ISBN|0-495-00561-4}}, [https://books.google.com/books?vid=ISBN0495005614&id=Idjxdi1IlFAC&pg=PA21&lpg=PA21&dq=Weber+Traditional+affectional+value+rational+instrumental&sig=Ib8EP0Ze_EPQgij7ns6lUSbNs2U Google Print, p. 21]
108. ^{{cite journal |first=Guenther |last=Roth |title=History and Sociology in the Work of Max Weber |journal=British Journal of Sociology |volume=27 |issue=3 |pages=306–18 |year=1979 |jstor=589618 |doi=10.2307/589618 }}
109. ^George Ritzer, Enchanting a Disenchanted World: Revolutionizing the Means of Consumption, Pine Forge Press, 2004, {{ISBN|0-7619-8819-X}}, [https://books.google.com/books?vid=ISBN076198819X&id=DznT_TbfKzMC&pg=PA55&lpg=PA55&dq=rationalization+%22iron+cage%22+%22polar+night+of+icy+darkness%22&sig=T4GVWJHDLYKbPVBg7lXN5KJFSb4 Google Print, p. 55]
110. ^"Between Mises and Keynes: An Interview with Gottfried von Haberler (1900–1995), The Austrian Economics Newsletter, 20 (1), 2000. [https://mises.org/journals/aen/aen20_1_1.asp Mises.org]
111. ^Habermas, Jürgen, The Philosophical Discourse of Modernity (originally published in German in 1985), Polity Press (1990), {{ISBN|0-7456-0830-2}}, p. 2.
112. ^Press release, Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics for 1974.
113. ^{{cite book|author=Eric J. Hobsbawm|title=The age of empire, 1875–1914|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=Xc4NAQAAMAAJ|accessdate=22 March 2011|year=1987|publisher=Pantheon Books|isbn=978-0-394-56319-0|page=152}}
114. ^{{cite book|author1=Paul Honigsheim|author2=Alan Sica|title=The unknown Max Weber|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=YoHSBnN9DY4C&pg=PA86|accessdate=24 March 2011|year=2003|publisher=Transaction Publishers|isbn=978-0-7658-0953-7|page=86}}
115. ^{{cite book|author=Liesbet Hooghe|title=The European Commission and the integration of Europe: images of governance|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=e15KnRiGipYC&pg=PA40|accessdate=23 March 2011|year=2001|publisher=Cambridge University Press|isbn=978-0-521-00143-4|page=40}}
116. ^{{cite book|authorlink1=|author1=Jörg Guido Hülsmann|title=Mises: The Last Knight of Liberalism|url=https://mises.org/books/lastknight.pdf|accessdate=30 March 2011|year=1995|publisher=Ludwig von Mises Institute|isbn=978-1-933550-18-3|pages=392–96}}
117. ^John K. Rhoads, Critical Issues in Social Theory, Penn State Press, 1991, {{ISBN|0-271-00753-2}}, [https://books.google.com/books?vid=ISBN0271007532&id=XVhOtKF3fKsC&pg=PA40&lpg=PA40&dq=Weber+antipositivist&sig=ZLl08PAGOCL2Z-B-aEn9zhhldfI Google Print, p. 40]
118. ^Kaesler, Dirk (1989). Max Weber: An Introduction to His Life and Work. University of Chicago Press, p. [https://books.google.com/books?vid=ISBN0226425606&id=shR9fsW9W8oC&pg=PA18&lpg=PA18&dq=Max+Weber+hospital&sig=38uV8JO6Z_TpXVF_FnjO9HdY3KE 18.] {{ISBN|0-226-42560-6}}
119. ^{{cite book|author=Basit Bilal Koshul|title=The postmodern significance of Max Weber's legacy: disenchanting disenchantment|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=BZwEI-o3PCIC&pg=PA11|accessdate=23 March 2011|year=2005|publisher=Macmillan|isbn=978-1-4039-6784-8|page=11}}
120. ^{{cite book|author=Dirk Käsler|title=Max Weber: an introduction to his life and work|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=v915AC-dflsC&pg=PA2|accessdate=24 March 2011|year=1988|publisher=University of Chicago Press|isbn=978-0-226-42560-3|page=2}}
121. ^Lutz Kaelber Max Weber's Personal Life, 1886–1893
122. ^{{cite book|author=Ludwig M. Lachmann|title=The legacy of Max Weber|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=pxAlydwrvcAC&pg=PA143|accessdate=22 March 2011|year=1970|publisher=Ludwig von Mises Institute|isbn=978-1-61016-072-8|page=143}}
123. ^{{cite book|author1=Hartmut Lehmann|author2=Guenther Roth|title=Weber's Protestant Ethic: Origins, Evidence, Contexts|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=HF3jdg0peNYC&pg=PA95|accessdate=24 March 2011|date=1995|publisher=Cambridge University Press|isbn=978-0-521-55829-7|page=95}}
124. ^[https://web.archive.org/web/20020620111309/http://www.webster.edu/~woolflm/weber.html Marianne Weber]. Last accessed on 18 September 2006. Based on {{cite book |last=Lengermann |first=P. |last2=Niebrugge-Brantley |first2=J. |year=1998 |title=The Women Founders: Sociology and Social Theory, 1830–1930 |location=Boston |publisher=McGraw-Hill |isbn=978-0-07-037169-9 }}
125. ^{{cite book|author=Wolfgang Justin Mommsen|title=Max Weber and German Politics, 1890–1920|year=1984|publisher=University of Chicago Press|isbn=978-0-226-53399-5|page=19}}
126. ^F. A. Hayek, [https://mises.org/books/memoirs_mises.pdf Introduction] to Mises's Memoirs, pp. xvi–xvii (1977).
127. ^{{cite book|author1=Wolfgang J. Mommsen|author2=Michael Steinberg|title=Max Weber and German Politics, 1890–1920|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=a99RC3rJoIgC&pg=PA54|accessdate=22 March 2011|date=1990|publisher=University of Chicago Press|isbn=978-0-226-53399-5|pages=54–56}}
128. ^Peter R. Baehr, Founders Classics Canons, Transaction Publishers, 2002, {{ISBN|0-7658-0129-9}}, [https://books.google.com/books?vid=ISBN0765801299&id=iRrnCPe66PYC&pg=PA22&lpg=PA22&dq=weber+founder+of+sociology&sig=2j-I_jptUjtqaKbiCjJpQgt0ohM Google Print, p. 22]
129. ^{{cite book|author=Randal Marlin|title=Propaganda and the ethics of persuasion|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=Zp38Ot2g7LEC&pg=PA155|accessdate=5 April 2011|year=2002|publisher=Broadview Press|isbn=978-1-55111-376-0|page=155}}
130. ^{{cite book|author=George Ritzer|title=Contemporary Sociological Theory and Its Classical Roots: The Basics|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=pX6pPwAACAAJ|accessdate=22 March 2011|date=2009|publisher=McGraw-Hill|isbn=978-0-07-340438-7|page=30}}
131. ^{{cite book|author=George Ritzer|title=Contemporary Sociological Theory and Its Classical Roots: The Basics|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=pX6pPwAACAAJ|accessdate=22 March 2011|date=2009|publisher=McGraw-Hill|isbn=978-0-07-340438-7|page=31}}
132. ^{{cite book|author=George Ritzer|title=Contemporary Sociological Theory and Its Classical Roots: The Basics|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=pX6pPwAACAAJ|accessdate=22 March 2011|date=2009|publisher=McGraw-Hill|isbn=978-0-07-340438-7|page=32}}
133. ^{{cite book|author=George Ritzer|title=Contemporary Sociological Theory and Its Classical Roots: The Basics|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=pX6pPwAACAAJ|accessdate=22 March 2011|date=2009|publisher=McGraw-Hill|isbn=978-0-07-340438-7|page=33}}
134. ^{{cite book|author=George Ritzer|title=Contemporary Sociological Theory and Its Classical Roots: The Basics|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=pX6pPwAACAAJ|accessdate=22 March 2011|date=2009|publisher=McGraw-Hill|isbn=978-0-07-340438-7|pages=35–37}}
135. ^{{cite book|author=George Ritzer|title=Contemporary Sociological Theory and Its Classical Roots: The Basics|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=pX6pPwAACAAJ|accessdate=22 March 2011|date=2009|publisher=McGraw-Hill|isbn=978-0-07-340438-7|pages=37–38}}
136. ^{{cite book|author=George Ritzer|title=Contemporary Sociological Theory and Its Classical Roots: The Basics|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=pX6pPwAACAAJ|accessdate=22 March 2011|date=2009|publisher=McGraw-Hill|isbn=978-0-07-340438-7|pages=38–42}}
137. ^{{cite book|author1=P.G.C. van Schie|author2=Gerrit Voermann|title=The dividing line between success and failure: a comparison of liberalism in the Netherlands and Germany in the 19th and 20th centuries|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=PWFMt03C6h0C&pg=PA64|accessdate=22 March 2011|year=2006|publisher=LIT Verlag Münster|isbn=978-3-8258-7668-5|page=64}}
138. ^{{cite journal |first=Arthur |last=Schweitzer |title=Frank Knight's Social Economics |journal=History of Political Economy |volume=7 |issue=3 |pages=279–92 |year=1975 |doi=10.1215/00182702-7-3-279 }}
139. ^M. Weber, "[https://web.archive.org/web/20000708094747/http://www.ne.jp/asahi/moriyuki/abukuma/weber/lecture/science_frame.html Science as a Vocation]", lecture given in 1918 at Munich University
140. ^"Methodological individualism", Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy. Retrieved 30 January 2010
141. ^Jordi Cat, "Political Economy: Theory, Practice, and Philosophical Consequences", supplement to "Otto Neurath", Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy (Fall 2010 Edition).
142. ^Richard Swedberg, "Max Weber as an Economist and as a Sociologist: Towards a Fuller Understanding of Weber's View of Economics – Critical Essay {{webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20110430173530/http://findarticles.com/p/articles/mi_m0254/is_4_58/ai_58496750/ |date=30 April 2011 }}", American Journal of Economics and Sociology, (1999).
143. ^{{cite book|author1=Richard Swedberg|author2=Ola Agevall|title=The Max Weber dictionary: key words and central concepts|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=_c3Mcnh8hCgC&pg=PA310|accessdate=22 March 2011|year=2005|publisher=Stanford University Press|isbn=978-0-8047-5095-0|page=310}}
144. ^{{cite book|author1=Richard Swedberg|author2=Ola Agevall|title=The Max Weber dictionary: key words and central concepts|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=_c3Mcnh8hCgC&pg=PA22|accessdate=22 March 2011|year=2005|publisher=Stanford University Press|isbn=978-0-8047-5095-0|pages=22–23}}
145. ^{{cite book|author1=Richard Swedberg|author2=Ola Agevall|title=The Max Weber dictionary: key words and central concepts|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=_c3Mcnh8hCgC&pg=PA283|accessdate=30 October 2011|year=2005|publisher=Stanford University Press|isbn=978-0-8047-5095-0|page=283}}
146. ^{{cite book|author1=Richard Swedberg|author2=Ola Agevall|title=The Max Weber dictionary: key words and central concepts|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=_c3Mcnh8hCgC&pg=PA64|accessdate=30 October 2011|year=2005|publisher=Stanford University Press|isbn=978-0-8047-5095-0|pages=64–65}}
147. ^Wolfgang J. Mommsen, The Political and Social Theory of Max Weber, University of Chicago Press, 1992, {{ISBN|0-226-53400-6}}, [https://books.google.com/books?vid=ISBN0226534006&id=kgF9bjMoocYC&pg=PA81&lpg=PA81&dq=Weber+1912+socialist&sig=AeL6fb399L7S_Mg0xvwigRHnZsQ Google Print, p. 81] [https://books.google.com/books?vid=ISBN0226533999&id=fcNJc-p2bjwC&pg=PA60&lpg=PA60&vq=Poland&dq=Max+Weber+hospital&sig=l3OeQlt7f9ePLosslRvI8gNY87Q p. 60,] [https://books.google.com/books?vid=ISBN0226533999&id=fcNJc-p2bjwC&pg=PA327&lpg=PA327&dq=Weber+Munich+left+1919&sig=kdzDUJ3wQb6DDhBiKmypM6S-XcY p. 327]
148. ^{{cite book|author1=Keith Tribe|title=Strategies of Economic Order: German Economic Discourse, 1750–1950|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=Y3Z4V9A8LzoC&pg=PA140|accessdate=30 March 2011|year=1995|publisher=Cambridge University Press|isbn=978-0-521-61943-1|pages=140–68}}
149. ^William Petersen, Against the Stream, Transaction Publishers, {{ISBN|0-7658-0222-8}}, 2004, [https://books.google.com/books?vid=ISBN0765802228&id=FHlTJ6HbY50C&pg=PA29&lpg=PA29&dq=weber+founder+of+sociology&sig=zxYCUTaFFvrlqcIX4guqG8pPyfU Google Print, p. 24]
150. ^{{cite book|author=Gianfranco Poggi|title=Weber: a short introduction|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=c5a2LWRh7uEC&pg=PA5|accessdate=22 March 2011|year=2006|publisher=Polity|isbn=978-0-7456-3489-0|page=5}}
151. ^{{cite book|author1=Max Weber|author2=Hans Heinrich Gerth|author3=Bryan S. Turner|title=From Max Weber: essays in sociology|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=Y_pqZS5q72UC&pg=PR1|accessdate=22 March 2011|date=1991|publisher=Psychology Press|isbn=978-0-415-06056-1|page=1}}
152. ^{{cite book|author=Wolfgang J. Mommsen|title=The Political and Social Theory of Max Weber: Collected Essays|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=kgF9bjMoocYC&pg=PA46|accessdate=22 March 2011|year=1992|publisher=University of Chicago Press|isbn= 978-0-226-53400-8|page= 46}}
153. ^[https://web.archive.org/web/20110411170016/http://www.newschool.edu/nssr/het/profiles/weber.htm Max Weber, 1864–1920], New School for Social Research
154. ^Lutz Kaelber, Max Weber's Dissertation
155. ^10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 {{cite web | last =Kim | first = Sung Ho |date=2007|url=http://plato.stanford.edu/entries/weber/ |title= Max Weber|publisher=Stanford | work = Encyclopaedia of Philosophy |accessdate= 17 February 2010}}
[63][64][65][66][67][68][69][70][71][72][73][74][75][76][77][78][79][80][81][82][83][84][85][86][87][88][89][90][91][92][93][94][95][96][97][98][99][100][101][102][103][104][105][106][107][108][109][110][111][112][113][114][115][116][117][118][119][120][121][122][123][124][125][126][127][128][129][130][131][132][133][134][135][136][137][138][139][140][141][142][143][144][145][146][147][148][149][150][151][152][153][154][155]
}}

Sources

  • {{Citation | first1 = Tony | last1 = Waters | first2 = Dagmar | last2 = Waters | title = Weber's Rationalism and Modern Society | place = New York | publisher = Palgrave-Macmillan | year = 2015}}.[https://www.academia.edu/12107148/Webers_Rationalism_and_Modern_Society_New_Translations_on_Politics_Bureaucracy_and_Social_Stratification]

Further reading

  • {{cite book |last=Anker |first=Guy |authorlink=|year=1972 |title=Sociologues allemands. Avec le dictionnaire de "l'Ethique protestante et l'esprit du capitalisme" de Max Weber |location=Neuchâtel |publisher=A la Baconnière. |language=French}}
  • {{cite book |last=Bruun |first=Hans Henrik |authorlink=Hans Henrik Reventlow Bruun |year=2007 |url=https://www.amazon.com/gp/reader/0754645290|title=Science, values, and politics in Max Weber's methodology |location=Aldershot, Ashgate |page=298 |series=Rethinking classical sociology.}}
  • {{cite book |editor-last=Green |editor-first=Robert |year=1959 |edition= |title=Problems in European Civilization, Protestantism and Capitalism: The Weber Thesis and Its Critics |location=Boston |publisher=Heath}}
  • {{cite book

| last = Haidenko
| first = Piama
| authormask =
| authorlink =
|author2=trans. H. Campbell Creighton
| author2-link =
| editor-first= Igor | editor-last= Kon
| editor-link = Igor Kon
| others =
| title = A History of Classical Sociology| chapter-url = http://su-ltd.mylivepage.ru/file/2715/6547_Kon_History_of_Classical_Sociology.zip
| archive-url = https://web.archive.org/web/20110514104128/http://su-ltd.mylivepage.ru/file/2715/6547_Kon_History_of_Classical_Sociology.zip
| chapter-format = DOC, DjVu
| type =
| edition =
| series =
| volume =
| year = 1989
| publisher = Progress Publishers
| location = Moscow
| isbn = 978-5-01-001102-4
| oclc =
| doi =
| bibcode =
| pages = 255–311
| nopp =
| chapter = The Sociology of Max Weber| chapterurl =
| ref =
}}
  • {{Cite book | last = Josephson-Storm | first = Jason | title = The Myth of Disenchantment: Magic, Modernity, and the Birth of the Human Sciences | publisher = University of Chicago Press | date = 2017 | url = https://books.google.com/books?id=xZ5yDgAAQBAJ | isbn = 978-0-226-40336-6 }}
  • {{cite book |last=Kemple |first=Thomas |url=https://books.google.com/?id=-VvvngEACAAJ |year=2014 |title=Intellectual work and the spirit of capitalism : Weber's calling |location=New York |publisher=Palgrave Macmillan |isbn=9781137377135 }}
  • {{Cite journal

|last= Kolko |first= Gabriel |authorlink= Gabriel Kolko |year= 1959
|title= A Critique of Max Weber's Philosophy of History
|url= https://www.scribd.com/doc/93720222/Kolko-A-Critique-of-Max-Weber-s-Philosophy-of-History
|archive-url= https://web.archive.org/web/20130530204109/http://www.scribd.com/doc/93720222/Kolko-A-Critique-of-Max-Weber-s-Philosophy-of-History
|dead-url= yes
|archive-date= 2013-05-30
|journal= Ethics |volume= 70 |issue= 1 |pages= 21–36
|jstor= 2379612 |ref= harv
|doi= 10.1086/291239 }}
  • {{cite book

|last1=Korotayev
|first1=Andrey
|authormask=
|authorlink=Andrey Korotayev
|first2=A.
|last2=Malkov
|first3=D.
|last3=Khaltourina
|author2-link=
|editor=
|editor2-last=
|editor2-first=
|editor-link=
|editor2-link=
|others=
|title=Introduction to Social Macrodynamics
|chapter-url=https://books.google.com/?id=tyoryrjrzUMC&printsec=frontcover&dq=ISBN5484004144#v=onepage&q&f=false
|url=https://books.google.com/?id=tyoryrjrzUMC&printsec=frontcover&dq=ISBN5484004144
|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20161018195055/https://books.google.com/books?id=tyoryrjrzUMC&printsec=frontcover&dq=ISBN5484004144&hl=en
|archivedate=18 October 2016
|chapter-format=Google Books
|accessdate=
|type=
|edition=
|series=
|volume=
|year=2006
|publisher=URSS
|location=Moscow
|isbn=978-5-484-00414-0
|oclc=
|doi=
|bibcode=
|page=
|pages=
|nopp=
|chapter=Chapter 6: Reconsidering Weber: Literacy and "the Spirit of Capitalism"
|chapterurl=
|dead-url=yes
|ref=
|df=
}}
  • Marra, Realino (1992), Dalla comunità al diritto moderno. La formazione giuridica di Max Weber. 1882–1889, Giappichelli, Torino
  • Marra, Realino (1995), La libertà degli ultimi uomini. Studi sul pensiero giuridico e politico di Max Weber, Giappichelli, Torino
  • Marra, Realino (2002), Capitalismo e anticapitalismo in Max Weber. Storia di Roma e sociologia del diritto nella genesi dell'opera weberiana, il Mulino, Bologna
  • {{cite book |last=Mitzman |first=Arthur |origyear=1970 |year=1985 |title=The Iron Cage: An Historical Interpretation of Max Weber |location=New Brunswick NJ |publisher=Transaction Books |isbn=978-0-87855-984-8}}
  • Quensel, Bernhard K. (2007), Max Webers Konstruktionslogik. Sozialökonomik zwischen Geschichte und Theorie, Nomos, {{ISBN|978-3-8329-2517-8}} [Revisiting Weber's concept of sociology against the background of his juristic and economic provenance within the framework of "social economics"]
  • {{cite book |last1=Radkau |first1=Joachim |authorlink=Joachim Radkau |origyear=2005 |year=2009 |title=Max Weber: a Biography |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=dqzZAAAAMAAJ|location=Cambridge |publisher=Polity |isbn=978-0-7456-4147-8|others=trans. Camiller }} [The most important work on Weber's life and torments since the biography by Marianne Weber]
  • {{cite book |first1=Max |last1=Rheinstein |first2=Edward |last2=Shils |year=1954 |title=Max Weber on Law in Economy and Society |location=Cambridge, MA |publisher=Harvard U.P. |isbn=978-0-674-55651-5}} [Translation, with long introduction, of Weber's main writings on law]
  • {{cite book |editor-last=Ritzer |editor-first=George |authorlink=George Ritzer |year=1996 |chapter=Sociological Theory |edition=fourth |title=Max Weber |location=New York |publisher=McGraw-Hill |isbn=978-0-07-114660-9}}
  • Roth, Guenther (2001), Max Webers deutsch-englische Familiengeschichte, J.C.B. Mohr (Paul Siebeck), {{ISBN|3-16-147557-7}}
  • Lawrence A. Scaff: Max Weber in America, Princeton University Press, Princeton/Oxford, England {{ISBN|978-0-691-14779-6}}
  • {{cite book |first=Gerhard |last=Stapelfeldt |authorlink=Gerhard Stapelfeldt |year=2004 |title=Kritik der ökonomischen Rationalität |language=German}}
  • {{cite book |editor-last=Swatos |editor-first=William H. |year=1990 |title=Time, Place, and Circumstance: Neo-Weberian Studies in Comparative Religious History |location=New York |publisher=Greenwood Press |isbn=978-0-313-26892-2}}
  • {{cite book |last=Swedberg |first=Richard |authorlink=Richard Swedberg |year=1998 |title=Max Weber and the Idea of Economic Sociology |location=Princeton |publisher=Princeton University Press |isbn=978-0-691-07013-1}}
  • {{cite journal |last=Swedberg |first=Richard |url=http://articles.findarticles.com/p/articles/mi_m0254/is_4_58/ai_58496750 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20130821022359/http://articles.findarticles.com/p/articles/mi_m0254/is_4_58/ai_58496750 |dead-url=yes |archive-date=2013-08-21 |title=Max Weber as an Economist and as a Sociologist |journal=American Journal of Economics and Sociology |date=October 1999 |doi=10.1111/j.1536-7150.1999.tb03385.x |volume=58 |issue=4 |pages=561–82}}
  • {{cite book |last1=Weber |first1=Marianne |authorlink=Marianne Weber |origyear=1926 |year=1988 |title=Max Weber: a Biography|location=New Brunswick |publisher=Transaction Books |isbn=978-0-471-92333-6|others=trans. Harry Zohn }}
  • {{cite book|authorlink=Marianne Weber|last=Weber|first=Marianne|title=Max Weber. Ein Lebensbild (in German)|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=ADKgjgEACAAJ|year=1926|publisher=Mohr}}
  • {{cite book|authorlink=Marianne Weber|last=Weber|first=Marianne|title=Max Weber|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=2G26AAAAIAAJ|year=1975|publisher=Wiley|isbn=978-0-471-92333-6}}

External links

{{Library resources box|by=yes|onlinebooks=no|about=yes|wikititle=Max Weber}}{{Sister project links|s=Author:Max Weber|wikt=no|v=no|n=no}}
Texts of his works
  • {{Internet Archive author |sname=Max Weber}}
  • {{Librivox author |id=663}}
  • Large collection of the German original texts
  • [https://web.archive.org/web/20041119141710/http://www.cpm.ehime-u.ac.jp/akamachomepage/akamac_e-text_links/Weber.html A collection of English translations]
  • Max Weber Reference Archive
  • Max Weber, On Politics (1919)
  • [https://web.archive.org/web/20020207003432/http://www.uni-potsdam.de/u/paed/Flitner/Flitner/Weber/index.htm Large collection of the German original texts]
  • [https://web.archive.org/web/20060630121301/http://www.sociosite.net/topics/weber.php A comprehensive collection of English translations and secondary literature]
  • [https://web.archive.org/web/20040210101459/http://ssr1.uchicago.edu/PRELIMS/Theory/weber.html Notes on several of Weber's works, merged into one text file]
Analysis of his works
  • Protestant Ethic Thesis by the Swatos' Encyclopedia of Religion and Society
  • Max Weber Studies journal
  • {{cite journal | last1 = McKinnon | first1 = AM | year = 2010 | title = Elective affinities of the Protestant ethic: Weber and the chemistry of capitalism | url = http://aura.abdn.ac.uk/bitstream/2164/3035/1/McKinnon_Elective_Affinities_final_non_format.pdf | journal = Sociological Theory | volume = 28 | issue = 1| pages = 108–26 | doi=10.1111/j.1467-9558.2009.01367.x}}
Other encyclopedic entries
  • {{sep entry|weber|Max Weber|Sung Ho Kim}}
  • {{Cite book |title=Max Weber (1864–1920) |url=http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/bios/Weber.html |work=The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics |edition=2nd |series=Library of Economics and Liberty |publisher=Liberty Fund |year=2008 }}
  • SocioSite: Famous Sociologists – Max Weber Information resources on life, academic work and intellectual influence of Max Weber. Editor: Dr. Albert Benschop (University of Amsterdam).
  • {{PM20|FID=pe/018241}}
{{Max Weber}}{{Navboxes
|title=Articles related to Max Weber
|list={{Social and political philosophy}}{{Liberalism}}{{Jurisprudence}}{{Historical School economists}}{{Positivism}}
}}{{Use dmy dates|date=April 2013}}{{Authority control}}{{DEFAULTSORT:Weber, Max}}

31 : Max Weber|1864 births|1920 deaths|19th-century German writers|19th-century German philosophers|20th-century German philosophers|Alldeutscher Verband members|Deaths from Spanish flu|Economic historians|German Democratic Party politicians|German economists|German Protestants|German sociologists|Heidelberg University alumni|Heidelberg University faculty|Historical school economists|Humboldt University of Berlin alumni|Ludwig Maximilian University of Munich faculty|Members of the Bavarian Academy of Sciences|National-Social Association politicians|People from Erfurt|People from the Province of Saxony|Philosophers of history|Philosophers of social science|Protestant philosophers|Rationality theorists|Sociologists of religion|University of Freiburg faculty|University of Göttingen alumni|Deaths from pneumonia|Symbolic interactionism

随便看

 

开放百科全书收录14589846条英语、德语、日语等多语种百科知识,基本涵盖了大多数领域的百科知识,是一部内容自由、开放的电子版国际百科全书。

 

Copyright © 2023 OENC.NET All Rights Reserved
京ICP备2021023879号 更新时间:2024/11/13 14:46:48