请输入您要查询的百科知识:

 

词条 Modigliani–Miller theorem
释义

  1. Historical background

  2. The theorem

  3. Without taxes

     Proposition I  Proposition II 

  4. With taxes

     Proposition I  Proposition II 

  5. Notes

  6. Further reading

  7. External links

The Modigliani–Miller theorem (of Franco Modigliani, Merton Miller) is an influential element of economic theory; it forms the basis for modern thinking on capital structure.[1] The basic theorem states that in the absence of taxes, bankruptcy costs, agency costs, and asymmetric information, and in an efficient market, the value of a firm is unaffected by how that firm is financed.[2] Since the value of the firm depends neither on its dividend policy nor its decision to raise capital by issuing stock or selling debt, the Modigliani–Miller theorem is often called the capital structure irrelevance principle.

The key Modigliani-Miller theorem was developed in a world without taxes. However, if we move to a world where there are taxes, when the interest on debt is tax-deductible, and ignoring other frictions, the value of the company increases in proportion to the amount of debt used.[3] And the source of additional value is due to the amount of taxes saved by issuing debt instead of equity.

Modigliani was awarded the 1985 Nobel Prize in Economics for this and other contributions.

Miller was a professor at the University of Chicago when he was awarded the 1990 Nobel Prize in Economics, along with Harry Markowitz and William F. Sharpe, for their "work in the theory of financial economics", with Miller specifically cited for "fundamental contributions to the theory of corporate finance".

Historical background

Miller and Modigliani derived and published their theorem when they were both professors at the Graduate School of Industrial Administration (GSIA) of Carnegie Mellon University. Despite limited prior experience in corporate finance, Miller and Modigliani were assigned to teach the subject to current business students. Finding the published material on the topic lacking, the professors created the theorem based on their own research{{citation needed|date=July 2018}}. The result of this was the article in the American Economic Review and what has later been known as the M&M theorem.

Miller and Modigliani published a number of follow-up papers discussing some of these issues. The theorem was first proposed by F. Modigliani and M. Miller in 1958.

The theorem

Consider two firms which are identical except for their financial structures. The first (Firm U) is unlevered: that is, it is financed by equity only. The other (Firm L) is levered: it is financed partly by equity, and partly by debt. The Modigliani–Miller theorem states that the value of the two firms is the same.

Without taxes

Proposition I

where

is the value of an unlevered firm = price of buying a firm composed only of equity, and is the value of a levered firm = price of buying a firm that is composed of some mix of debt and equity. Another word for levered is geared, which has the same meaning.[4]

To see why this should be true, suppose an investor is considering buying one of the two firms, U or L. Instead of purchasing the shares of the levered firm L, he could purchase the shares of firm U and borrow the same amount of money B that firm L does. The eventual returns to either of these investments would be the same. Therefore the price of L must be the same as the price of U minus the money borrowed B, which is the value of L's debt.

This discussion also clarifies the role of some of the theorem's assumptions. We have implicitly assumed that the investor's cost of borrowing money is the same as that of the firm, which need not be true in the presence of asymmetric information, in the absence of efficient markets, or if the investor has a different risk profile than the firm.

Proposition II

here

  • is the expected rate of return on equity, or cost of equity.
  • is the expected rate of return on borrowings, or cost of debt.
  • is the debt-to-equity ratio.

A higher debt-to-equity ratio leads to a higher required return on equity, because of the higher risk involved for equity-holders in a company with debt. The formula is derived from the theory of weighted average cost of capital (WACC).

These propositions are true under the following assumptions:

  • no transaction costs exist, and
  • individuals and corporations borrow at the same rates.

These results might seem irrelevant (after all, none of the conditions are met in the real world), but the theorem is still taught and studied because it tells something very important. That is, capital structure matters precisely because one or more of these assumptions is violated. It tells where to look for determinants of optimal capital structure and how those factors might affect optimal capital structure.

With taxes

Proposition I

where

  • is the value of a levered firm.
  • is the value of an unlevered firm.
  • is the tax rate () x the value of debt (D)
  • the term assumes debt is perpetual

This means that there are advantages for firms to be levered, since corporations can deduct interest payments. Therefore leverage lowers tax payments. Dividend payments are non-deductible.

Proposition II

where:

  • is the required rate of return on equity, or cost of levered equity = unlevered equity + financing premium.
  • is the company cost of equity capital with no leverage (unlevered cost of equity, or return on assets with D/E = 0).
  • is the required rate of return on borrowings, or cost of debt.
  • is the debt-to-equity ratio.
  • is the tax rate.

The same relationship as earlier described stating that the cost of equity rises with leverage, because the risk to equity rises, still holds. The formula, however, has implications for the difference with the WACC. Their second attempt on capital structure included taxes has identified that as the level of gearing increases by replacing equity with cheap debt the level of the WACC drops and an optimal capital structure does indeed exist at a point where debt is 100%.

The following assumptions are made in the propositions with taxes:

  • corporations are taxed at the rate on earnings after interest,
  • no transaction costs exist, and
  • individuals and corporations borrow at the same rate.

Notes

1. ^{{Cite journal |title=The Modigliani and Miller Theorem and the Integration of Financial Markets |last=Titman |first=Sheridan |journal=Financial Management |year=2002 |volume=31 |issue=1 |pages=101–115 |doi=10.2307/3666323 |jstor=3666323 }}
2. ^MIT Sloan Lecture Notes, Finance Theory II, Dirk Jenter, 2003{{Unreliable source?|date=May 2018}}
3. ^ Fernandes, Nuno. Finance for Executives: A Practical Guide for Managers. NPV Publishing, 2014, p. 82.
4. ^Arnold G. (2007)

Further reading

{{More footnotes|date=March 2009}}
  • {{cite book |title=Principles of Corporate Finance |last=Brealey |first=Richard A. |authorlink= |author2=Myers, Stewart C. |year=2008 |edition=9th |origyear=1981 |publisher=McGraw-Hill/Irwin |location=Boston |isbn=978-0-07-340510-0 |pages= |title-link=Principles of Corporate Finance }}
  • {{cite book |title=The Quest for Value: The EVA management guide |last=Stewart |first=G. Bennett |authorlink= |year=1991 |publisher=HarperBusiness |location=New York |isbn=978-0-88730-418-7 |pages= }}
  • {{cite journal | last = Modigliani | first = F. | authorlink = |author2=Miller, M. | year = 1958 | title = The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and the Theory of Investment | journal = American Economic Review | volume = 48 | issue = 3 | pages = 261–297 | doi = | jstor = 1809766 | accessdate = | quote = }}
  • {{cite journal | last = Modigliani | first = F. | authorlink = |author2=Miller, M. | year = 1963 | title = Corporate income taxes and the cost of capital: a correction | journal = American Economic Review | volume = 53 | issue = 3 | pages = 433–443 | doi = | jstor = 1809167 | accessdate = | quote = }}
  • {{cite journal | last = Miles | first = J. | authorlink = |author2=Ezzell, J. | year = 1980 | title = The weighted average cost of capital, perfect capital markets and project life: a clarification | journal = Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis | volume = 15 | issue = 3| pages = 719–730 | id = | jstor = 2330405 | accessdate = | quote =| doi =10.2307/2330405 | citeseerx = 10.1.1.455.6733 }}
  • {{cite book |last=Sargent |first=Thomas J. |authorlink=Thomas Sargent |title=Macroeconomic Theory |location=London |publisher=Academic Press |edition=Second |year=1987 |isbn=978-0-12-619751-8 |pages=157–162 }}
  • Suresh P. Sethi, Extension of the Miller and Modigliani theory to allow for share repurchases, Mathematical Finance Letters, Vol 2017 (2017), Article ID 3 http://scik.org/index.php/mfl/article/view/3138
  • {{cite journal|last1=Sethi|first1=S.P.|last2=Derzko|first2=N.A.|last3=Lehoczky|first3=J.P.|title=A Stochastic Extension of the Miller-Modigliani Framework|journal=Mathematical Finance|date=1991|volume=1|issue=4|pages=57–76|doi=10.1111/j.1467-9965.1991.tb00019.x}}
  • {{cite journal|last1=Sethi|first1=S.P.|title=When Does the Share Price Equal the Present Value of Future Dividends?|journal=Economic Theory|date=1996|volume=8|page=307–319}}

External links

  • Ruben D Cohen: An Implication of the Modigliani-Miller Capital Structuring Theorems on the Relation between Equity and Debt
{{corporate finance and investment banking}}{{DEFAULTSORT:Modigliani-Miller Theorem}}

3 : Capital (economics)|Economics theorems|Financial economics

随便看

 

开放百科全书收录14589846条英语、德语、日语等多语种百科知识,基本涵盖了大多数领域的百科知识,是一部内容自由、开放的电子版国际百科全书。

 

Copyright © 2023 OENC.NET All Rights Reserved
京ICP备2021023879号 更新时间:2024/11/16 18:13:45