词条 | Oligopoly |
释义 |
An oligopoly ({{IPAc-en|ɒ|l|ɪ|ˈ, from Ancient Greek ὀλίγος (olígos) "few" + πωλεῖν (poleîn) "to sell") is a market form wherein a market or industry is dominated by a small number of large sellers (oligopolists). Oligopolies can result from various forms of collusion which reduce competition and lead to higher prices for consumers. Oligopolies have their own market structure.[1] With few sellers, each oligopolist is likely to be aware of the actions of the others. According to game theory, the decisions of one firm therefore influence and are influenced by decisions of other firms. Strategic planning by oligopolists needs to take into account the likely responses of the other market. Entry barriers include high investment requirements, strong consumer loyalty for existing brands and economies of scale. DescriptionOligopoly is a common market form where a number of firms are in competition. As a quantitative description of oligopoly, the four-firm concentration ratio is often utilized. This measure expresses, as a percentage, the market share of the four largest firms in any particular industry. For example, as of fourth quarter 2008, if we combine total market share of Verizon Wireless, AT&T, Sprint, and T-Mobile, we see that these firms, together, control 97% of the U.S. cellular telephone market.{{Citation needed|date=January 2014}} Oligopolistic competition can give rise to both wide-ranging and diverse outcomes. In some situations, particular companies may employ restrictive trade practices (collusion, market sharing etc.) in order to inflate prices and restrict production in much the same way that a monopoly does. Whenever there is a formal agreement for such collusion, between companies that usually compete with one another, this practice is known as a cartel. A prime example of such a cartel is OPEC, which has a profound influence on the international price of oil. Firms often collude in an attempt to stabilize unstable markets, so as to reduce the risks inherent in these markets for investment and product development.{{Citation needed|date=February 2010}} There are legal restrictions on such collusion in most countries. There does not have to be a formal agreement for collusion to take place (although for the act to be illegal there must be actual communication between companies)–for example, in some industries there may be an acknowledged market leader which informally sets prices to which other producers respond, known as price leadership. In other situations, competition between sellers in an oligopoly can be fierce, with relatively low prices and high production. This could lead to an efficient outcome approaching perfect competition. The competition in an oligopoly can be greater when there are more firms in an industry than if, for example, the firms were only regionally based and did not compete directly with each other. Thus the welfare analysis of oligopolies is sensitive to the parameter values used to define the market's structure. In particular, the level of dead weight loss is hard to measure. The study of product differentiation indicates that oligopolies might also create excessive levels of differentiation in order to stifle competition. Oligopoly theory makes heavy use of game theory to model the behavior of oligopolies:
Characteristics
Oligopolies in countries with competition lawsOligopolies become "mature" when they realise they can profit maximise through joint profit maximising. As a result of operating in countries with enforced competition laws, the Oligopolists will operate under tacit collusion, which is collusion through an understanding that if all the competitors in the market raise their prices, then collectively all the competitors can achieve economic profits close to a monopolist, without evidence of breaching government market regulations. Hence, the kinked demand curve for a joint profit maximising Oligopoly industry can model the behaviours of oligopolists pricing decisions other than that of the price leader (the price leader being the firm that all other firms follow in terms of pricing decisions). This is because if a firm unilaterally raises the prices of their good/service, and other competitors do not follow then, the firm that raised their price will then lose a significant market as they face the elastic upper segment of the demand curve. As the joint profit maximising achieves greater economic profits for all the firms, there is an incentive for an individual firm to "cheat" by expanding output to gain greater market share and profit. In Oligopolist cheating, and the incumbent firm discovering this breach in collusion, the other firms in the market will retaliate by matching or dropping prices lower than the original drop. Hence, the market share that the firm that dropped the price gained, will have that gain minimised or eliminated. This is why on the kinked demand curve model the lower segment of the demand curve is inelastic. As a result, price rigidity prevails in such markets. ModelingThere is no single model describing the operation of an oligopolistic market.[7] The variety and complexity of the models exist because you can have two to 10 firms competing on the basis of price, quantity, technological innovations, marketing, and reputation. However, there are a series of simplified models that attempt to describe market behavior by considering certain circumstances. Some of the better-known models are the dominant firm model, the Cournot–Nash model, the Bertrand model and the kinked demand model. Cournot–Nash model{{Main article|Cournot competition}}The Cournot–Nash model is the simplest oligopoly model. The model assumes that there are two "equally positioned firms"; the firms compete on the basis of quantity rather than price and each firm makes an "output of decision assuming that the other firm's behavior is fixed."[8] The market demand curve is assumed to be linear and marginal costs are constant. To find the Cournot–Nash equilibrium one determines how each firm reacts to a change in the output of the other firm. The path to equilibrium is a series of actions and reactions. The pattern continues until a point is reached where neither firm desires "to change what it is doing, given how it believes the other firm will react to any change."[9] The equilibrium is the intersection of the two firm's reaction functions. The reaction function shows how one firm reacts to the quantity choice of the other firm.[10] For example, assume that the firm 1's demand function is P = (M − Q2) − Q1 where Q2 is the quantity produced by the other firm and Q1 is the amount produced by firm 1,[11] and M=60 is the market. Assume that marginal cost is CM=12. Firm 1 wants to know its maximizing quantity and price. Firm 1 begins the process by following the profit maximization rule of equating marginal revenue to marginal costs. Firm 1's total revenue function is RT = Q1 P = Q1(M − Q2 − Q1) = MQ1 − Q1 Q2 − Q12. The marginal revenue function is .[12] RM = CM M − Q2 − 2Q1 = CM 2Q1 = (M − CM) − Q2 Q1 = (M − CM)/2 − Q2/2 = 24 − 0.5 Q2 [1.1] Q2 = 2(M − CM) − 2Q1 = 96 − 2 Q1 [1.2] Equation 1.1 is the reaction function for firm 1. Equation 1.2 is the reaction function for firm 2. To determine the Cournot–Nash equilibrium you can solve the equations simultaneously. The equilibrium quantities can also be determined graphically. The equilibrium solution would be at the intersection of the two reaction functions. Note that if you graph the functions the axes represent quantities.[13] The reaction functions are not necessarily symmetric.[14] The firms may face differing cost functions in which case the reaction functions would not be identical nor would the equilibrium quantities. Bertrand model{{Main article|Bertrand competition}}The Bertrand model is essentially the Cournot–Nash model except the strategic variable is price rather than quantity.[15] The model assumptions are:
The only Nash equilibrium is PA = PB = MC. Neither firm has any reason to change strategy. If the firm raises prices it will lose all its customers. If the firm lowers price P < MC then it will be losing money on every unit sold.[17] The Bertrand equilibrium is the same as the competitive result.[18] Each firm will produce where P = marginal costs and there will be zero profits.[15] A generalization of the Bertrand model is the Bertrand–Edgeworth model that allows for capacity constraints and more general cost functions. Oligopolistic market: Kinked demand curve model{{Main article|Kinked demand}}According to this model, each firm faces a demand curve kinked at the existing price.[19] The conjectural assumptions of the model are; if the firm raises its price above the current existing price, competitors will not follow and the acting firm will lose market share and second if a firm lowers prices below the existing price then their competitors will follow to retain their market share and the firm's output will increase only marginally.[20] If the assumptions hold then:
The gap in the marginal revenue curve means that marginal costs can fluctuate without changing equilibrium price and quantity.[19] Thus prices tend to be rigid. ExamplesIn industrialized economies, barriers to entry have resulted in oligopolies forming in many sectors, with unprecedented levels of competition fueled by increasing globalization. Market shares in an oligopoly are typically determined by product development and advertising. For example, there are now only a small number of manufacturers of civil passenger aircraft, though Brazil (Embraer) and Canada (Bombardier) have participated in the small passenger aircraft market sector. Oligopolies have also arisen in heavily-regulated markets such as wireless communications: in some areas only two or three providers are licensed to operate. World wideAircraft
Finance
Food
Technology
Australia
CanadaMedia
Other
India
European Union
United Kingdom
United StatesMedia
Other
Demand curveIn an oligopoly, firms operate under imperfect competition. With the fierce price competitiveness created by this sticky-upward demand curve, firms use non-price competition in order to accrue greater revenue and market share. "Kinked" demand curves are similar to traditional demand curves, as they are downward-sloping. They are distinguished by a hypothesized convex bend with a discontinuity at the bend–"kink". Thus the first derivative at that point is undefined and leads to a jump discontinuity in the marginal revenue curve. Classical economic theory assumes that a profit-maximizing producer with some market power (either due to oligopoly or monopolistic competition) will set marginal costs equal to marginal revenue. This idea can be envisioned graphically by the intersection of an upward-sloping marginal cost curve and a downward-sloping marginal revenue curve (because the more one sells, the lower the price must be, so the less a producer earns per unit). In classical theory, any change in the marginal cost structure (how much it costs to make each additional unit) or the marginal revenue structure (how much people will pay for each additional unit) will be immediately reflected in a new price and/or quantity sold of the item. This result does not occur if a "kink" exists. Because of this jump discontinuity in the marginal revenue curve, marginal costs could change without necessarily changing the price or quantity. The motivation behind this kink is the idea that in an oligopolistic or monopolistically competitive market, firms will not raise their prices because even a small price increase will lose many customers. This is because competitors will generally ignore price increases, with the hope of gaining a larger market share as a result of now having comparatively lower prices. However, even a large price decrease will gain only a few customers because such an action will begin a price war with other firms. The curve is therefore more price-elastic for price increases and less so for price decreases. Theory predicts that firms will enter the industry in the long run. ==See also== {{Div col|colwidth=30em}}
Notes1. ^{{cite web|url=http://www.ftc.gov/bc/edu/pubs/consumer/general/zgen01.shtm|title=Competition Counts|date=11 June 2013|publisher=|accessdate=23 March 2018}} 2. ^Perloff, J. Microeconomics Theory & Applications with Calculus. page 445. Pearson 2008. 3. ^1 2 Hirschey, M. Managerial Economics. Rev. Ed, page 451. Dryden 2000. 4. ^1 Negbennebor, A: Microeconomics, The Freedom to Choose CAT 2001{{page needed|date=September 2010}} 5. ^Negbennebor, A: Microeconomics, The Freedom to Choose page 291. CAT 2001 6. ^Melvin & Boyes, Microeconomics 5th ed. page 267. Houghton Mifflin 2002 7. ^1 Colander, David C. Microeconomics 7th ed. Page 288 McGraw-Hill 2008. 8. ^This statement is the Cournot conjectures. Kreps, D.: A Course in Microeconomic Theory page 326. Princeton 1990. 9. ^Kreps, D. A Course in Microeconomic Theory. page 326. Princeton 1990. 10. ^Kreps, D. A Course in Microeconomic Theory. Princeton 1990.{{page needed|date=September 2010}} 11. ^Samuelson, W & Marks, S. Managerial Economics. 4th ed. Wiley 2003{{page needed|date=September 2010}} 12. ^RM = M − Q2 − 2Q1. can be restated as RM = (M − Q2) − 2Q1. 13. ^Pindyck, R & Rubinfeld, D: Microeconomics 5th ed. Prentice-Hall 2001{{page needed|date=September 2010}} 14. ^Pindyck, R & Rubinfeld, D: Microeconomics 5th ed. Prentice-Hall 2001 15. ^1 Samuelson, W. & Marks, S. Managerial Economics. 4th ed. page 415 Wiley 2003. 16. ^There is nothing to guarantee an even split. Kreps, D.: A Course in Microeconomic Theory page 331. Princeton 1990. 17. ^This assumes that there are no capacity restriction. Binger, B & Hoffman, E, 284–85. Microeconomics with Calculus, 2nd ed. Addison-Wesley, 1998. 18. ^Pindyck, R & Rubinfeld, D: Microeconomics 5th ed.page 438 Prentice-Hall 2001. 19. ^1 2 Pindyck, R. & Rubinfeld, D. Microeconomics 5th ed. page 446. Prentice-Hall 2001. 20. ^Simply stated the rule is that competitors will ignore price increases and follow price decreases. Negbennebor, A: Microeconomics, The Freedom to Choose page 299. CAT 2001 21. ^1 Negbennebor, A. Microeconomics: The Freedom to Choose. page 299. CAT 2001 22. ^{{citation| date=November 2008 | publisher=Datamonitor| title=Airlines Industry Profile: United States | pages=13–14}} 23. ^{{cite news|title=Manufacturers work on perfecting aircraft tires|url=http://www.rubbernews.com/article/20130509/NEWS/130509939/manufacturers-work-on-perfecting-aircraft-tires|newspaper=Rubber News|date=May 9, 2013}} 24. ^{{citation| date=September 2008 | publisher=Datamonitor| title=Accountancy Industry Profile: Global}}{{page needed|date=September 2010}} 25. ^{{cite web|url=https://www.ft.com/content/693ba6b8-aebd-11e3-a088-00144feab7de|title=Subscribe to read|website=Financial Times|accessdate=23 March 2018}} 26. ^{{citation|author=SHETH Jagdish, SISODIA Rajendra|title=The Rule of Three|publisher=Boston Publishing.|publication-place=New York}}{{page needed|date=September 2010}} 27. ^{{cite web |last1=Fisher |first1=Caroline |last2=Watkins |first2=Jerry |title=Australia - Reuters Institute Digital News Report |url=http://www.digitalnewsreport.org/survey/2016/australia-2016/ |website=Reuters Institute |publisher=Reuters Institute |accessdate=1 August 2018}} 28. ^{{cite web |title=Woolworths increases lead in $100b+ grocery war |url=http://www.roymorgan.com/findings/7537-woolworths-increases-lead-in-$100b-plus-grocery-war-201803230113 |website=Roy Morgan |publisher=Roy Morgan |accessdate=1 August 2018 |language=en}} 29. ^http://cwta.ca/CWTASite/english/facts_figures_downloads/SubscribersStats_en_2008_Q4.pdf 30. ^http://www.crtc.gc.ca/eng/publications/reports/policymonitoring/2008/cmr2008.pdf 31. ^{{citation|date=January 2011|url=https://www.telegraph.co.uk/finance/newsbysector/banksandfinance/8266582/Big-banks-running-an-oligopoly-says-Virgin-Money-chief.html|title=Big banks running an oligopoly, says Virgin Money chief}} 32. ^{{citation|date=31 October 2007|url=http://news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/business/4785544.stm|title=Probe says 'too few supermarkets'|publisher=BBC News|accessdate=3 April 2009}} 33. ^{{citation| date=November 2008 | publisher=Datamonitor| title=Textile Washing Products Industry Profile: United Kingdom}}{{page needed|date=September 2010}} 34. ^{{citation|date=27 March 2014|url=https://www.bbc.co.uk/news/business-26734203|title='Big six' energy firms face competition inquiry |publisher=BBC News}} 35. ^{{cite web|url=http://www.boxofficemojo.com/studio/?view=parent&view2=yearly&yr=2013&p=.htm|title=2013 Market Share and Box Office Results by Movie Studio|work=boxofficemojo.com}} 36. ^{{citation|year=2008|edition=2nd|publisher=McGraw Hill|title=Rodman, George. Mass Media in a Changing World. New York}}{{page needed|date=September 2010}} 37. ^{{cite news|url=https://www.reuters.com/article/2012/03/08/us-apple-ebooks-idUSBRE82715J20120308|title=Justice Department may sue Apple, publishers on e-books|publisher=Reuters|date=8 Mar 2012|accessdate=14 Mar 2012|first=Diane|last=Bartz}} 38. ^{{cite news|url=https://www.forbes.com/sites/timworstall/2012/03/08/now-the-justice-department-wants-to-sue-apple/|title=Now the Justice Department Wants to Sue Apple|publisher=Forbes|author=Tim Worstall|date=8 Mar 2012|accessdate=14 Mar 2012}} 39. ^{{cite news|url=https://www.wsj.com/articles/SB10001424052970203961204577267831767489216|title=US Warns Apple, Publishers|publisher=Wall Street Journal|author1=Thomas Catan|author2=Jeffrey A. Trachtenberg|date=9 Mar 2012|accessdate=14 Mar 2012}} 40. ^{{cite web|url=http://www.slideshare.net/chetansharma/us-wireless-market-q4-2008-and-2008-update-mar-2009-chetan-sharma-consulting|title=Us Wireless Market Q4 2008 And 2008 Update Mar 2009 Chetan Sharma…|author=Chetan Sharma|work=slideshare.net}} 41. ^{{cite web|url=https://www.cnbc.com/id/32918263|title=Roginsky: The Health Insurance Oligopoly|first=Julie Roginsky, CNBC|last=Contributor|date=18 September 2009|publisher=|accessdate=23 March 2018}} 42. ^{{cite web|last1=Sorkin|first1=Andrew Ross|title=As Oil Prices Fall, Airfares Still Stay High|url=https://www.nytimes.com/2015/03/24/business/dealbook/as-oil-prices-fall-air-fares-still-stay-high.html|website=NYTimes.com|publisher=New York Times|accessdate=24 March 2015}} 43. ^{{cite web|url=http://www.investopedia.com/articles/markets/051915/costco-target-or-walmart-which-best-bet.asp|title=Costco, Target or Walmart: Which is the Best Bet?|first=Dan|last=Moskowitz|date=19 May 2015|publisher=|accessdate=23 March 2018}} 44. ^{{cite web|url=https://finance.yahoo.com/news/cvs-walgreens-duopoly-thats-hard-174012061.html|title=CVS and Walgreens: A Duopoly That's Hard to Ignore|publisher=|accessdate=23 March 2018}} Further reading
References{{reflist|30em}}External links{{commons category}}
2 : Market structure|Oligopoly |
随便看 |
|
开放百科全书收录14589846条英语、德语、日语等多语种百科知识,基本涵盖了大多数领域的百科知识,是一部内容自由、开放的电子版国际百科全书。