词条 | Oskar R. Lange |
释义 |
|name = Oskar R. Lange |school_tradition = Neo-Marxian economics[1] |image = Oskar_Lange_20-65.jpg |caption = Oskar Lange |birth_date = 27 July 1904 |birth_place = Tomaszów Mazowiecki, Congress Poland |death_date = {{Death date and age|1965|10|2|1904|7|27|df=yes}} |death_place = London, United Kingdom |nationality = Polish |field = Political economy |influences = Karl Marx, Vilfredo Pareto, Léon Walras |influenced = Abba P. Lerner, Don Patinkin, Jan Tinbergen,[2] Robin Hahnel |contributions = Paretian Revival in general equilibrium theory |awards = |signature = }}{{Socialism sidebar|People}}Oskar Ryszard Lange (27 July 1904 – 2 October 1965) was a Polish economist and diplomat. He is best known for advocating the use of market pricing tools in socialist systems and providing a model of market socialism.[3] During his stay in the United States, Lange was a sought-after academic teacher and researcher in mathematical economics. Later in communist Poland, he was a member of the Central Committee of the Polish United Workers' Party and a believer in centrally-managed economy.[4] CareerLange was born in Tomaszów Mazowiecki as son of Arthur Julius Lange and Sophie Albertine Rosner. His ancestors had emigrated at the beginning of the 19th century from Germany to Poland.[5] He studied law and economics at the University of Kraków, where he defended a doctoral dissertation in 1928 under Adam Krzyżanowski. From 1926 to 1927 Lange worked at the Ministry of Labor in Warsaw, and then was a research assistant at the University of Kraków (1927–31). He married Irene Oderfeld in 1932. In 1934, a Rockefeller Foundation fellowship brought him to England, from where he emigrated to the United States in 1937. Lange became a professor at the University of Chicago in 1938 and was naturalized as a U.S. citizen in 1943.[6] Joseph Stalin, who identified Lange as a person of leftist and pro-Soviet sympathies, prevailed on President Franklin D. Roosevelt to obtain a passport for Lange to visit the Soviet Union in an official capacity, so that Stalin could speak with him personally; he also proposed offering him a position in the future Polish cabinet. The State Department was opposed to Lange traveling as an emissary because they felt that his political views represented neither Americans of Polish descent nor American public opinion in general. Lange's trip to the Soviet Union in 1944 caused further controversy, as the newly-establish Polish American Congress condemned him and defended the interests of the London-based Polish government-in-exile. Lange returned to the United States at the end of May and met, at Roosevelt's request, with Prime Minister Stanisław Mikołajczyk of the government-in-exile, who was on a visit in Washington. Lange stressed how reasonable Stalin was prepared to be (Stalin told him of the Soviet desire to preserve independent Poland under a coalition government), and asked the State Department to put pressure on the exiled Polish leadership to reach an understanding with the Soviet leader.[7]Towards the end of World War II, Lange broke with the Polish government-in-exile and transferred his support to the Lublin Committee (PKWN) sponsored by the Soviet Union. Lange served as a go-between for Roosevelt and Stalin during the Yalta Conference discussions on post-war Poland. After the war ended in 1945, Lange returned to Poland. He then renounced his American citizenship and went back to the US in the same year as the Polish People's Republic's first ambassador to the United States.[8] In 1946, Lange also served as Poland's delegate to the United Nations Security Council. From 1947 he lived in Poland.[6] Oskar Lange worked for the Polish government while continuing his academic pursuits at the University of Warsaw and the Main School of Planning and Statistics. He was deputy chairman of the Polish Council of State in 1961–65, and as such one of four acting chairmen of the Council of State (a head of state function). Academic contributionsThe bulk of Lange's contributions to economics came during his American interlude of 1933–45. Despite being an ardent socialist, Lange deplored the Marxian labor theory of value because he was very much a believer in the neoclassical theory of price. In the history of economics, he is probably best known for his work On the Economic Theory of Socialism published in 1936, where he famously put Marxian economics and neoclassical economics together. In the book, Lange advocated the use of market tools (especially the neoclassical pricing theory) in economic planning of socialism and Marxism. He proposed that central planning boards set prices through "trial and error", making adjustments as shortages and surpluses occur rather than relying on a free price mechanism. Under this system, central planners would arbitrarily pick a price for products manufactured in government factories and raise it or reduce, depending on whether it resulted in shortages or gluts. After this economic experiment had been run a few times, mathematical methods would be employed to plan the economy: if there were shortages, prices would be raised; if there were surpluses, prices would be lowered.[9] Raising the prices would encourage businesses to increase production, driven by their desire to increase profits, and in doing so eliminate the shortage. Lowering the prices would encourage businesses to curtail production in order to prevent losses, which would eliminate the surplus. In Lange's opinion, such simulation of market mechanism would be capable of effectively managing supply and demand. Proponents of this idea argued that it combines the advantages of a market economy with those of socialist economy. With the utilization of this idea, Lange claimed, a state-run economy would be at least as efficient as a capitalist or private market economy. He argued that this was possible, provided the government planners used the price system as if in a market economy and instructed state industry managers to respond parametrically to state-determined prices (minimize cost, etc.). Lange's argument was one of the pivots of the socialist calculation debate with the Austrian School economists. At that time, the view among English socialists of the Fabian Society was that Lange had won the debate.[9] His works provided the earliest model of market socialism.[10] Lange also made contributions in various other areas. He was one of the leading lights of the "Paretian Revival" in general equilibrium theory during the 1930s. In 1942, he provided one of the first proofs of the First and Second Welfare Theorems. He initiated the analysis of stability of general equilibrium (1942, 1944). His critique of the quantity theory of money (1942) prompted his student Don Patinkin to develop his remarkable "integration" of money into general equilibrium theory. Lange made several seminal contributions to the development of neoclassical synthesis (1938, 1943, 1944). He worked on integrating classical economics and neoclassical economics into a single theoretical structure (e.g. 1959). In his final years, Lange also worked on cybernetics and the use of computers for economic planning. The International Institute of Social Studies (ISS) awarded Oskar Lange an honorary fellowship in 1962. Bibliography
See also
Notes1. ^Bruce Williams, Making and Breaking Universities, Macleay Press, p. 103. 2. ^J. Tinbergen, 1991. "Solving the Most Urgent Problems First", in Michael Szenberg (ed.) 1993, Eminent Economists: Their Life Philosophies, Cambridge University Press, p. 279 (cambridge.org). 3. ^Thadeusz Kowalik, [1987] 2008. "Lange, Oskar Ryszard (1904–1965)", The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. Abstract. 4. ^Witold Gadomski, Rynek trzyma smycz [Gadomski o książce Belki] (The market holds the leash [Gadomski about Belka's book]). 11 June 2016. Rynek trzyma smycz. wyborcza.pl. Retrieved 26 June 2016. 5. ^Who is Who in Central and East-Europe 1933/34 Zürich 1935, referenced in: Beate Kosmala: Juden und Deutsche im polnischen Haus. Tomaszów Mazowiecki 1914–1939. Berlin 2001, p. 227. 6. ^1 Halik Kochanski (2012). The Eagle Unbowed: Poland and the Poles in the Second World War, pp. 612–613. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. {{ISBN|978-0-674-06814-8}}. 7. ^Halik Kochanski (2012). The Eagle Unbowed: Poland and the Poles in the Second World War, pp. 441–444. 8. ^{{cite news|url=https://pqasb.pqarchiver.com/chicagotribune/access/478271952.html?dids=478271952:478271952&FMT=ABS&FMTS=ABS:AI&type=historic&date=Aug+20%2C+1945&author=&pub=Chicago+Tribune&desc=LANGE+TO+YIELD+CITIZENSHIP+TO+BE+POLES'+ENVOY&pqatl=google|title=Lange to yield citizenship to be Poles' envoy|work=Chicago Daily Tribune|date=20 August 1945}} 9. ^1 Dalmia, Shikha, 2012, Cheer Up, Liberty Lovers, Schumpeter Was Wrong, Reason, Feb. 23. 10. ^Robin Hahnel, 2005.Economic Justice and Democracy, Routlege, page 170 References
External links{{Wikiquote}}
28 : 1904 births|1965 deaths|People from Tomaszów Mazowiecki|People from Piotrków Governorate|Polish Socialist Party politicians|Members of the Central Committee of the Polish United Workers' Party|Members of the Polish Sejm 1947–52|Members of the Polish Sejm 1952–56|Members of the Polish Sejm 1957–61|Members of the Polish Sejm 1961–65|Members of the Polish Sejm 1965–69|Ambassadors of Poland to the United States|Permanent Representatives of Poland to the United Nations|Diplomats of the Polish People's Republic|Polish economists|Polish emigrants to the United States|American people of Polish descent|Polish-American culture in Chicago|People who lost United States citizenship|20th-century economists|Marxian economists|General equilibrium theorists|Jagiellonian University alumni|University of Chicago faculty|Members of the Polish Academy of Sciences|Fellows of the Econometric Society|Recipients of the Order of the Builders of People's Poland|Commanders of the Order of Polonia Restituta |
随便看 |
开放百科全书收录14589846条英语、德语、日语等多语种百科知识,基本涵盖了大多数领域的百科知识,是一部内容自由、开放的电子版国际百科全书。