词条 | Paul A. Baran |
释义 |
|name = Paul Alexander Baran |school_tradition = Neo-Marxian economics[1] |image = Baran-paul-a-1957.jpg |caption = Economist Paul A. Baran as he appeared in the late 1950s. |birth_date = 25 August 1909 |birth_place = Mykolaiv,[2] Kherson Governorate, Russian Empire (present-day Ukraine) |death_date = {{Death date and age|1964|3|26|1909|6|22|df=yes}} |death_place = Palo Alto, California, U.S. |nationality = American |field = Macroeconomics |influences = Karl Marx, Michał Kalecki, Josef Steindl, John Kenneth Galbraith |influenced = Immanuel Wallerstein, Richard D. Wolff |contributions = Economic surplus |awards = |signature = }}{{American socialism|Theorists}}Paul Alexander Baran ({{IPAc-en|ˈ|b|æ|r|ən}}; 25 August 1909 – 26 March 1964) was an American Marxist economist. In 1951 Baran was promoted to full professor at Stanford University and Baran was the only tenured Marxian economist in the United States until his death in 1964. Baran wrote The Political Economy of Growth in 1957 and co-authored Monopoly Capital with Paul Sweezy.[3] Life and workBaran was born in Imperial Russia. His father, a Menshevik, left Russia for Vilna (then Poland) in 1917. From Vilna the Baran family moved to Berlin, and then, in 1925 back to Moscow, but Paul stayed in Germany to finish his secondary school. In 1926 he attended the Plekhanov Institute in Moscow. He left again for Germany in 1928 accepting an appointment as an assistant on agricultural research with his advisor, Dr. Friedrich Pollock. Baran remained in Germany associated with the Frankfurt School Institute for Social Research. He received the Diplom-Volkswirt (graduate degree in political economy, equivalent to a master's degree) in 1931 from the Schlesische Friedrich-Wilhelm University of Breslau. He next wrote a dissertation under Emil Lederer on economic planning, and received his PhD from the University of Berlin in 1933. During these years in Germany, he met Rudolf Hilferding, author of Finance Capital and wrote under the pen name of Alexander Gabriel for the German Social Democratic Party journal Die Gesellschaft. After the Nazi regime took power, Baran fled to Paris and then back to the USSR, and then to Vilna, (then in Poland). With the Molotov–Ribbentrop Pact and just before the Nazi invasion of Poland he emigrated to the US, where he enrolled at Harvard and received a master's degree. Short of funds, he left the PhD program and worked for the Brookings Institution and then for the Office of Price Administration and then the Office of Strategic Services. He worked under John Kenneth Galbraith at the Strategic Bombing Survey traveling to post-war Germany and Japan. Baran then worked for the United States Department of Commerce and lectured at George Washington University. He then worked for the Federal Reserve Bank of New York before resigning to join academia. He married Elena Djatschenko, had a son Nicholas but soon divorced.[4] Baran had his academic career in the United States, teaching at Stanford University from 1949.[3] From 1949, he was an active participant in the formulation of editorial ideas and opinions in Monthly Review magazine edited by Paul Sweezy and Leo Huberman. Baran visited Cuba in 1960 along with Sweezy and Huberman, and was greatly inspired. In 1962 he revisited Moscow, Iran, and Yugoslavia. In his last years he worked on Monopoly Capital with Sweezy. He died from a heart attack in 1964[3] before it was completed by Sweezy. He is associated with the Neo-Marxian economics. Baran introduced the concept of "economic surplus" to deal with novel complexities raised by the dominance of monopoly capital. With Paul Sweezy, Baran elaborated the importance of this innovation, its consistency with Marx's labor concept of value, and supplementary relation to Marx's category of surplus value.[5] Monthly Review has recently published a book of correspondence between Sweezy and Baran, which illuminates the development of their ideas on political economy, and in particular, their collaboration in writing their seminal work, Monopoly Capital. See The Age of Monopoly Capital, The Selected Correspondence of Paul A. Baran and Paul M. Sweezy, 1949–1964, edited by Nicholas Baran and John Bellamy Foster, Monthly Review Press, New York, 2017.[6] According to Baran's categories, "Actual economic surplus" is "the difference between society's actual current output and its actual current consumption," and hence is equal to current savings or accumulation. Potential economic surplus," in contrast, is "the difference between that output that could be produced in a given natural and technical environment with the help of employable productive resources, and what might be regarded as essential consumption." Baran also introduced the concept of "planned surplus"—a category that could only be operationalized in a rationally planned socialist society. This was defined as "the difference between society's 'optimum' output available in a historically given natural and technological environment under conditions of planned 'optimal' utilization of all available productive resources, and some chosen 'optimal' volume of consumption."[7] Baran used the surplus concept to analyze underdeveloped economies (or what are now more optimistically called "developing economies") in his The Political Economy of Growth. Baran with Paul M. Sweezy applied the surplus concept to the contemporary US economy in Monopoly Capital. Selected bibliography
References1. ^Shahrukh Rafi Khan, A History of Development Economics Thought: Challenges and Counter-challenges, Routledge, 2014, p. 39. 2. ^{{cite web|url=http://histsoc.stanford.edu/pdfmem/BaranP.pdf|title=Memorial Resolution: Paul A Baran|format=PDF|work=Stanford Historical Society|last1=Reder|first1=Melvin W|last2=Tarshis|first2=Lorie|last3=Smith|first3=Thomas C|accessdate=2 May 2010|deadurl=yes|archiveurl=https://web.archive.org/web/20100707053935/http://histsoc.stanford.edu/pdfmem/BaranP.pdf|archivedate=7 July 2010|df=}} 3. ^1 2 Robert W. McChesney. The Monthly Review Story: 1949–1984 {{webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20091107230040/http://www.monthlyreview.org/mrzine/mcchesney060507.html |date=2009-11-07 }} Monthly Review Foundation. 4. ^Paul Sweezy, "Paul Baran: A Memoir" in Sweezy and Leo Huberman, eds, (1965); Paul A. Baran (1910–1964): A Collective Portrait, Monthly Review Press, New York. 5. ^Baran, P.A. & Sweezy, P.M. (2012). "Some Theoretical Implications". Monthly Review. 64 (3). 6. ^The entire archive of their correspondence is available at the Stanford University Archives, http://www.oac.cdlib.org/findaid/ark:/13030/c8xs5zkx/. 7. ^{{cite book|last=Baran|first=Paul A.|title=The Political Economy of Growth|year=1957|publisher=Monthly Review Press|location=New York|pages=22–23, 41–42}} Further reading
External links{{wikiquote}}
13 : 1909 births|1964 deaths|People from Mykolaiv|Ukrainian Jews|American people of Ukrainian-Jewish descent|Soviet emigrants to the United States|Harvard University alumni|American Marxists|Development economists|Marxian economists|Marxist theorists|20th-century American economists|Jewish socialists |
随便看 |
|
开放百科全书收录14589846条英语、德语、日语等多语种百科知识,基本涵盖了大多数领域的百科知识,是一部内容自由、开放的电子版国际百科全书。