词条 | FTC v. Actavis, Inc. |
释义 |
|Litigants=FTC v. Actavis, Inc. |ArgueDate=March 25 |ArgueYear=2013 |DecideDate=June 17 |DecideYear=2013 |FullName=Federal Trade Commission v. Actavis, Inc., et al. |USVol=570 |USPage=___(2013) |ParallelCitations=133 S. Ct. 2223; 185 L. Ed. 2d 175; 2013 U.S. LEXIS 4545; 106 U.S.P.Q.2d 1953 |Docket=12-416 |OralArgument=https://www.oyez.org/cases/2010-2019/2012/2012_12_416/argument |OpinionAnnouncement=https://www.oyez.org/cases/2010-2019/2012/2012_12_416/opinion |Prior=Injunction denied, In re Androgel Antitrust Lit., 687 F. Supp. 2d [https://www.leagle.com/decision/infdco20100224720 1371] (N.D. Ga. 2010); affirmed, complaint dismissed, FTC v. Watson Pharmaceuticals, Inc., 677 F.3d [https://www.leagle.com/decision/infco20120425096 1298](11th Cir. 2012). |Holding=Reverse payment settlements of patent litigations are not immune from antitrust liability. U.S. Supreme Court reversed and remanded the Eleventh Circuit ruling. |SCOTUS=2010-2016 |Majority=Breyer |JoinMajority=Kennedy, Ginsburg, Sotomayor, Kagan |Dissent=Roberts |JoinDissent=Scalia, Thomas |NotParticipating = Alito |LawsApplied=Sherman Act; Hatch-Waxman Act }} FTC v. Actavis, Inc., 570 U.S. ___, 133 S. Ct. 2223 (2013),[1] was a United States Supreme Court decision in which the Court held that the FTC could make an antitrust challenge under the rule of reason against a so-called pay-for-delay agreement, also referred to as a reverse payment patent settlement. Such an agreement is one in which a drug patentee pays another company, ordinarily a generic drug manufacturer, to stay out of the market, thus avoiding generic competition and a challenge to patent validity. The FTC sought to establish a rule that such agreements were presumptively illegal, but the Court ruled only that the FTC could bring a case under more general antitrust principles permitting a defendant to assert justifications for its actions under the rule of reason. BackgroundHatch-WaxmanUnder the "paragraph IV route" of the Hatch-Waxman Act, a generic drug manufacturer can assure the U.S. Food and Drug Commission (FDA) that it would not infringe upon the patent of a brand-name drug by proving that the patent was invalid or that the sale of the generic drugs will not violate the brand-name's patent. This would constitute a challenge to the patent, and usually lead to litigation between the brand-name and generic manufacturers. The FDA then must withhold approving the generic drugs for a 30-month period while the courts resolve the dispute. If the dispute does not resolve within that period, the FDA could then approve the generic for the market.[2] Androgel and generic versionsRespondent Solvay Pharmaceuticals filed a New Drug Application in 1999 and received a patent in 2003 for its brand-name drug, Androgel, used for treating low testosterone levels in men. Two generic-drug companies, Actavis and Paddock filed patents for generic drugs that were modeled after Androgel later that year. Solvay then sued Actavis for patent infringement under "paragraph IV" litigation, but the FDA eventually approved Actavis's generic drug for the market after the dispute over the validity of Solvay's patent had continued for three years.[3] Rather than bringing its generic drug to the market, Actavis instead entered into a reverse payment settlement agreement with Solvay in 2006. Under the terms of the agreement, Actavis would keep its generic drug off the market for a "specified number of years" and also agree "to promote Androgel to doctors."[3] FTC suesThe Federal Trade Commission filed suit, alleging that Actavis had unlawfully abandoned its patent challenge by agreeing to share in the "monopoly profits" of Solvay, and withdrawing its generic drug from the market. Solvay was simultaneously accused of attempting to extend its monopoly rights further than what its patent would have conferred if otherwise left as valid.[4] Rulings of lower courtsBoth the district court and Eleventh Circuit dismissed the plaintiff's claims. The district court ruled that the settlements did not provide unreasonable restraints outside the scope of the patents.[5] The Eleventh Circuit ruled that the FTC had not shown that the reverse payment settlement excluded competition any more than the patent would have, stating that "although a patent holder may be able to escape the jaws of competition by sharing monopoly profits with the first one or two generic challengers, those profits will be eaten away as more and more generic companies enter the waters." Furthermore, the appeals court ruled, courts cannot require parties to litigate further in order to avoid antitrust liability.[6] Opinion of the CourtThe Court reversed the rulings of the lower courts. Justice Stephen Breyer delivered the opinion of a 5-3 Court. Chief Justice John Roberts dissented, joined by Justices Antonin Scalia and Clarence Thomas. Justice Samuel Alito took no part in the consideration or decision of the case. Majority opinionThe majority opinion reversed the Eleventh Circuit's ruling that antitrust laws do not apply to patent holders so long as the anticompetitive effects of their reverse payment settlements fall within the scope their patent monopoly. Instead, the majority decided that the antitrust question cannot be answered only by measuring the anticompetitive effects against patent law policy, but also by measuring against "procompetitive" antitrust law policies. In other words, even if Solvay's reverse payment settlement falls within the exclusionary scope of its patent, that by itself does not "immunize the agreement from antitrust attack."[7] Instead, the Court insisted, "patent and antitrust policies are both relevant in determining the 'scope of the patent monopoly'—and consequently antitrust law immunity—that is conferred by a patent."[8] In addition, the majority pointed out the uniqueness of reverse payment settlements in which "the party with no claim on damages" is the one that pays the other party for the sake of staying out of the patentee's market contrasts with how a settlement would normally proceed, in which the patentee demands an amount as reparation for the damages done by the patent infringer. Noting this unusual distinction, the majority argued that reverse payments are not a normal form of settlement in patent suits, and thus cannot be scrutinized solely under the lens of patent law when there seems to be an anticompetitive purpose. Past precedent, such as United States v. Singer Mfg. Co.[9] and United States v. New Wrinkle, Inc.,[10] shows that patent litigation settlements can be used for anticompetive purposes, so they must be considered in light of antitrust policy. as the Court did in such cases, in order to determine whether "patent law policy offsets the antitrust law policy strongly favoring competition."[11] Furthermore, patent policy by itself is concerned lest agreements shield invalid patents from scrutiny;the Court has held such agreements unlawful "so the public will not continually be required to pay tribute to would-be monopolists without need or justification.' "[12] To be sure, there is a general legal policy favoring settlements. But "this patent-related factor should not determine the result here."[13] The Court gave five reasons why it should not:
Due to the many factors and complexities that determine whether a reverse payment settlement causes anticompetitive harm (“its size, its scale in relation to the payor’s anticipated future litigation costs, its independence from other services for which it might represent payment, and the lack of any other convincing justification”), the Court held, the FTC must still "prove its case as in other rule-of-reason cases" and thus ruled that reverse payments are neither presumptively legal nor presumptively illegal.[15] The Court refused to be more specific about how the lower court should resolve the case on remand and what factors should be weighed againstg one another in the analysis. It said: As in other areas of law, trial courts can structure antitrust litigation so as to avoid, on the one hand, the use of antitrust theories too abbreviated to permit proper analysis, and, on the other, consideration of every possible fact or theory irrespective of the minimal light it may shed on the basic question—that of the presence of significant unjustified anticompetitive consequences. We therefore leave to the lower courts the structuring of the present rule-of-reason antitrust litigation.[15] DissentIn contrast to the majority, the dissent rejected the application of antitrust law that the majority used for this case, arguing that it was a "novel approach" and "without any support in statute." Pointing out that a "patent carves out an exception to the applicability of antitrust laws," the dissenting opinion argued that it is only when a patent holder acts beyond the scope of its granted monopoly does scrutiny under antitrust law become applicable. Otherwise, the patent holder is operating within his rights to be excepted from antitrust liability. As a result, the dissent believed that the real question was whether the reverse payment settlement "gives Solvay monopoly power beyond what the patent already gave it."[16] The dissent concluded: The majority today departs from the settled approach separating patent and antitrust law, weakens the protections afforded to innovators by patents, frustrates the public policy in favor of settling, and likely undermines the very policy it seeks to promote by forcing generics who step into the litigation ring to do so without the prospect of cash settlements. I would keep things as they were and not subject basic questions of patent law to an unbounded inquiry under antitrust law, with its treble damages and famously burdensome discovery.[17] What constitutes a reverse payment?Since, the Actavis decision, a controversy has arisen over what constitutes a reverse payment agreement, which is subject to antitrust scrutiny pursuant to Actavis? Suppose non-monetary consideration is paid—is that a reverse payment? The controversy largely centers on so-called No-AG agreements. A no-AG agreement (a no-authorized generic agreement) is an agreement by which a brand name drug firm agrees not to launch an authorized generic (a generic version of the brand name company's brand name drug, which it advertises as "authorized") in exchange for the generic manufacturer's promise not to market its generic product for a specified time.[18] Commentary● Both sides declared victory after the opinion issued, and lauded the majority opinion. FTC Chairwoman Edith Ramirez issued a press release that praised the decision as having "made it clear that pay-for-delay agreements between brand and generic drug companies are subject to antitrust scrutiny, and it has rejected the attempt by branded and generic companies to effectively immunize these agreements from the antitrust laws."[19] Defendant Actavis's President and CEO Paul Bisaro stated: We are pleased that the Court rejected the FTC’s proposed ‘quick look’ test, and did not rule that settlement agreements are presumptively unlawful. Rather, the Court has established that the ‘rule of reason’ be applied, and left it to the lower courts to determine if the benefits of the settlement outweigh harm to consumers.[20] ● Lyle Dennison, in the SCOTUS Blog, opined that the decision presented a challenge to what has been the prominent practice of "pay-for-delay" settlements in the drug industry. With this ruling, he said, patent owners no longer maintain immunity from the "rule of reason" scrutiny of antitrust laws when making reverse payment settlements, even if the settlements are only for the terms of the patents. In effect, this limits patent owners' scope of power in holding their monopolies. In addition, as a result, using reverse–payment settlements to resolve patent disputes now carries a greater risk of coming under litigation, and being ruled as infringing of antitrust laws.[21] ● Alan Morrison, in the SCOTUS Blog, considers how one should litigate a reverse-payments case, based on the Court's opinion. Since not all reverse payments are anticompetitive, Morrison says, "A company with a very solid patent, but with the knowledge that there is always a chance it may be struck down and with the realization that even winning a patent case costs lots of money, may be willing to make a modest payment to gain several years of peace and profits." so the problem is "separating the wheat from the chaff." The Supreme Court in Actavis says "the antitrust laws forbid only those payments that are "large and unjustified.' " But what does that mean, Morrison asks, and tries to answer: First, what is the baseline or even the universe against which large is to be measured? Annual gross revenues or net profits of the pioneer and/or the generic would be convenient yardsticks. But most companies have many products, with different sales and profit ratios, and so the company-wide figures are likely to be an inappropriate measure of what is too large. Moreover, in all these deals, the non-compete lasts only so long, and so the open period has to be somehow taken into account. Even harder to decide is whether the payment is justified. How does one factor in probability of establishing liability? How does one determine what damages would probably be? "In short, the Court may have created a theoretically beautiful lawsuit model that cannot work in practice." Morrison proposes a court’s determination that the public interest is served by the settlement and an antitrust immunity if the court approves it. He concludes, "While a court-approval procedure would not be without difficulty, it seems like a much more sensible approach than the kind of open-ended litigation over whether a prior settlement was too large and not justified, which is what the Court in Actavis created."[22] ● Bloomberg Law writers thought that the implications of the decision could impact the effect of antitrust laws on general intellectual property cases, outside of the drug industry. Specifically, the outcome could be applied to general cases regarding "patent pools, cross-licensing arrangements, and more routine patent licensing decisions."[23] ● Jason S. Oliver, in Lexology, argued that the case will reduce the number of settlements with respect to patent litigation. However, the Court "did not set forth a clear structure for reviewing settlement agreements and left this job to the district courts," which still leaves the full effect of this case to be determined, even with respect to generic drug manufacturers.[24] See also
References{{BBstyle}}1. ^{{ussc|name=FTC v. Actavis, Inc.|link=|volume=570|year=2013|docket=12-416}}. {{usgovpd}} 2. ^133 S. Ct. at 2228. 3. ^1 133 S. Ct. at 2229. 4. ^133 S. Ct. at 2229-30. 5. ^{{cite court |litigants=In re Androgel Antitrust Lit. |vol=687 |reporter=F. Supp. 2d |opinion=1371 |pinpoint= |court=N.D. Ga. |date=2010 |url=https://www.leagle.com/decision/infdco20100224720 |accessdate=2018-07-01 |quote=}} 6. ^{{cite court |litigants=FTC v. Watson Pharmaceuticals, Inc. |vol=677 |reporter=F.3d |opinion=1298 |pinpoint=1312 |court= |date=2012 |url=https://www.leagle.com/decision/infco20120425096 |accessdate=2018-07-01 |quote=}} 7. ^133 S. Ct. at 2230. 8. ^133 S. Ct. at 2231. 9. ^{{ussc|name=United States v. Singer Mfg. Co.|link=|volume=374|page=174|pin=|year=1963}}. 10. ^{{ussc|name=United States v. New Wrinkle, Inc.|link=|volume=342|page=378|pin=|year=1952}}. 11. ^133 S. Ct. at 2233. 12. ^133 S. Ct. at 2232 (quoting {{ussc|name=Lear, Inc. v. Adkins|volume=395|page=653|pin=670|year=1969}}). 13. ^133 S. Ct. at 2234. 14. ^133 S. Ct. at 2234-37. 15. ^1 133 S. Ct. at 2238. 16. ^133 S. Ct. at 2237. 17. ^133 S. Ct. at 2247. 18. ^See Note: Rebalancing Pay-For-Delay: Why No-Authorized Generic Agreements Should Be Subject To Higher Antitrust Scrutiny, 32 {{smallcaps|Cardozo Arts & Ent.}} L.J. 683, 685 (2014). 19. ^Statement of FTC Chairwoman Edith Ramirez on the U.S. Supreme Court’s Decision in FTC v. Actavis, Inc.” (June 17, 2013). 20. ^U.S. Supreme Court Reverses U.S. Court of Appeals Decision in FTC v. Actavis (June 17, 2013). 21. ^Lyle Denniston, Opinion Recap: Pay to Delay in Deep Trouble {{smallcaps|SCOTUSblog}} (June 17, 2013). Retrieved 20 October 2013. 22. ^Alan Morrison, Commentary: Subjecting reverse payments in patent cases to antitrust scrutiny: Sounds like a good idea, but can it work?, {{smallcaps|SCOTUSblog}} (July 2013). 23. ^Mark Botti & Jessica Hoke, Redefining the Border Between Intellectual Property and Antitrust: Implications of FTC v. Actavis, {{smallcaps|Bloomberg Law}}. Retrieved 9 November 2013. 24. ^Jason S. Oliver, Federal Trade Commission v. Actavis, Inc. et al. – Supreme Court holds reverse payment settlement agreements to be analyzed under “rule of reason” approach, {{smallcaps|Lexology}} (June 21, 2013). Retrieved 9 November 2013. External links
| case = FTC v. Actavis, Inc., 570 U.S. ___ (2013) | courtlistener =https://www.courtlistener.com/opinion/902769/ftc-v-actavis-inc/ | googlescholar = https://scholar.google.com/scholar_case?case=11793515772117153465 | justia =https://supreme.justia.com/cases/federal/us/570/12-416/ | oyez =https://www.oyez.org/cases/2012/12-416 | other_source1 = Supreme Court (slip opinion | other_url1 = https://www.supremecourt.gov/opinions/12pdf/12-416_m5n0.pdf
| case = Valley Drug Co. v. Geneva Pharmaceuticals, Inc., No. 02-12091 | other_source1 = United States Court of Appeals for the Eleventh Circuit | other_url1 = http://www.ca11.uscourts.gov/opinions/ops/200212091.pdf
8 : United States antitrust case law|United States patent case law|United States intellectual property case law|2013 in United States case law|United States Supreme Court cases|Federal Trade Commission litigation|Pharmaceutical industry in the United States|United States Supreme Court cases of the Roberts Court |
随便看 |
|
开放百科全书收录14589846条英语、德语、日语等多语种百科知识,基本涵盖了大多数领域的百科知识,是一部内容自由、开放的电子版国际百科全书。