请输入您要查询的百科知识:

 

词条 Historical materialism
释义

  1. History and development

     Origins  Continued development 

  2. Key ideas

  3. Key implications in the study and understanding of history

  4. Trajectory of historical development

      Primitive communism    The ancient mode of production    The feudal mode of production    The capitalist mode of production    The communist mode of production    The lower-stage of communism    The higher-stage of communism  

  5. Warnings against misuse

  6. Criticisms

  7. See also

  8. References

      Footnotes    Bibliography  

  9. Further reading

{{for|the academic journal|Historical Materialism (journal)}}{{use British English Oxford spelling|date=April 2018}}{{use dmy dates|date=April 2018}}{{short desc|Marxist historiography}}{{over-quotation|date=December 2018}}{{Marxism|Philosophy}}Historical materialism (also materialist conception of history) is a methodology used by some communist and Marxist historiographers that focuses on human societies and their development through history, arguing that history is the result of material conditions rather than ideas. This was first articulated by Karl Marx (1818–1883) as the "materialist conception of history."[1] It is principally a theory of history which asserts that the material conditions of a society's mode of production or in Marxist terms, the union of a society's productive forces and relations of production, fundamentally determine society's organization and development. Historical materialism is an example of Marx and Engel's scientific socialism, attempting to show that socialism and communism are scientific necessities rather than philosophical ideals.[2]

Historical materialism is materialist as it does not believe that history has been driven by individual's consciousness or ideals, but rather ascribes to the philosophical monism that matter is the fundamental substance of nature and henceforth the driving force in all of world history; this drove Marx and other historical materialists to abandon ideas such as rights (e.g. "right to life, liberty, and property" as liberalism professed). In contrast, idealists believe that human consciousness creates reality rather than the materialist conception that material reality creates human consciousness. This put Marx in direct conflict with groups like the liberals and egoists who believed that reality was governed by some set of ideals.[3]

Communism is for us not a state of affairs which is to be established, an ideal to which reality [will] have to adjust itself. We call communism the real movement which abolishes the present state of things. The conditions of this movement result from the premises now in existence.

-Karl Marx, The German Ideology[4]

Historical materialism looks for the causes of developments and changes in human society in the means by which humans collectively produce the necessities of life. It posits that social classes and the relationship between them, along with the political structures and ways of thinking in society, are founded on and reflect contemporary economic activity.{{sfn|Fromm|1961}}

Since Marx's time, the theory has been modified and expanded by some writers. It now has many Marxist and non-Marxist variants. Many Marxists contend that historical materialism is a scientific approach to the study of history: scientific socialism.[5]

History and development

Origins

While Marx never used the words "historical materialism" to describe his theory of history, it nevertheless first appears in Friedrich Engels' 1880 work Utopian and Scientific,[6] to which Marx wrote an introduction for the French edition.[7] By 1892, Friedrich Engels indicated that he accepted the broader usage of the term "historical materialism," writing in an introduction to an English edition of Socialism: Utopian and Scientific;

{{quotation|This book defends what we call "historical materialism", and the word materialism grates upon the ears of the immense majority of British readers... I hope even British respectability will not be overshocked if I use, in English as well as in so many other languages, the term "historical materialism", to designate that view of the course of history which seeks the ultimate cause and the great moving power of all important historic events in the economic development of society, in the changes in the modes of production and exchange, in the consequent division of society into distinct classes, and in the struggles of these classes against one another.[8]}}

Marx's initial interest in materialism is evident in his doctoral thesis which compared the philosophical atomism of Democritus with the materialist philosophy of Epicurus[9]{{sfn|Foster|1999}} as well as his close reading of Adam Smith and other writers in classical political economy.

Marx and Engels first state and detail their materialist conception of history within the pages of The German Ideology, written in 1845. The book, which structural Marxists such as Louis Althusser[10] regard as Marx's first 'mature' work, is a lengthy polemic against Marx and Engels' fellow Young Hegelians and contemporaries Ludwig Feuerbach, Bruno Bauer, and Max Stirner. Stirner's 1844 work The Unique and its Property had a particularly strong impact[11] on the worldview of Marx and Engels: Stirner's blistering critique of morality and whole-hearted embrace of egoism prompted the pair to formulate a conception of socialism along lines of self-interest rather than simple humanism alone, grounding that conception in the scientific study of history.[12]

Perhaps Marx's clearest formulation of historical materialism resides in the preface to his 1859 book A Contribution to the Critique of Political Economy:

In the social production of their existence, men inevitably enter into definite relations, which are independent of their will, namely relations of production appropriate to a given stage in the development of their material forces of production. The totality of these relations of production constitutes the economic structure of society, the real foundation, on which arises a legal and political superstructure and to which correspond definite forms of consciousness. The mode of production of material life conditions the general process of social, political and intellectual life. It is not the consciousness of men that determines their existence, but their social existence that determines their consciousness. At a certain stage of development, the material productive forces of society come into conflict with the existing relations of production or – this merely expresses the same thing in legal terms – with the property relations within the framework of which they have operated hitherto. From forms of development of the productive forces these relations turn into their fetters. Then begins an era of social revolution. The changes in the economic foundation lead sooner or later to the transformation of the whole immense superstructure. In studying such transformations it is always necessary to distinguish between the material transformation of the economic conditions of production, which can be determined with the precision of natural science, and the legal, political, religious, artistic or philosophic – in short, ideological forms in which men become conscious of this conflict and fight it out. Just as one does not judge an individual by what he thinks about himself, so one cannot judge such a period of transformation by its consciousness, but, on the contrary, this consciousness must be explained from the contradictions of material life, from the conflict existing between the social forces of production and the relations of production.{{sfn|Marx|1977}}

Continued development

In a foreword to his essay Ludwig Feuerbach and the End of Classical German Philosophy (1886), three years after Marx's death, Engels claimed confidently that "the Marxist world outlook has found representatives far beyond the boundaries of Germany and Europe and in all the literary languages of the world."{{sfn|Engels|1946}} Indeed, in the years after Marx and Engels' deaths, "historical materialism" was identified as a distinct philosophical doctrine and was subsequently elaborated upon and systematized by Orthodox Marxist and Marxist–Leninist thinkers such as Eduard Bernstein, Karl Kautsky, Georgi Plekhanov and Nikolai Bukharin. This occurred despite the fact that many of Marx's earlier works on historical materialism, including The German Ideology, remained unpublished until the 1930's.

In the early years of the 20th century, historical materialism was often treated by socialist writers as interchangeable with dialectical materialism, a formulation never used by Marx or Engels.[13] According to many Marxists influenced by Soviet Marxism, historical materialism is a specifically sociological method, while dialectical materialism refers to the more general, abstract philosophy underlying Marx and Engels' body of work. This view is based on Joseph Stalin's pamphlet Dialectical and Historical Materialism, as well as textbooks issued by the Institute of Marxism–Leninism of the Central Committee of the Communist Party of the Soviet Union.[14]

The substantivist ethnographic approach of economic anthropologist and sociologist Karl Polanyi bears similarities to historical materialism. Polanyi distinguishes between the formal definition of economics as the logic of rational choice between limited resources and a substantive definition of economics as the way humans make their living from their natural and social environment.[15] In The Great Transformation (1944), Polanyi asserts that both the formal and substantive definitions of economics hold true under capitalism, but that the formal definition falls short when analyzing the economic behavior of pre-industrial societies, whose behavior was more often governed by redistribution and reciprocity.[16] While Polanyi was influenced by Marx, he rejected the primacy of economic determinism in shaping the course of history, arguing that rather than being a realm unto itself, an economy is embedded within its contemporary social institutions, such as the state in the case of the market economy.[17]

Perhaps the most notable recent exploration of historical materialism is G. A. Cohen's A Defence,{{sfn|Cohen|2000}} which inaugurated the school of Analytical Marxism. Cohen advances a sophisticated technological-determinist interpretation of Marx "in which history is, fundamentally, the growth of human productive power, and forms of society rise and fall according as they enable or impede that growth."[18]

Several scholars have argued that historical materialism ought to be revised in the light of modern scientific knowledge.{{who|date=December 2018}} Jürgen Habermas believes historical materialism "needs revision in many respects", especially because it has ignored the significance of communicative action.[19]

Göran Therborn has argued that the method of historical materialism should be applied to historical materialism as intellectual tradition, and to the history of Marxism itself.[20]

In the early 1980s, Paul Hirst and Barry Hindess elaborated a structural Marxist interpretation of historical materialism.[21]

Regulation theory, especially in the work of Michel Aglietta draws extensively on historical materialism.[22]Spiral dynamics shows similarities to historical materialism.{{how|date=October 2018}}[23]

Key ideas

{{quote
|text= Society does not consist of individuals, but expresses the sum of interrelations, the relations within which these individuals stand. |sign=  Karl Marx, Grundrisse, 1858{{sfn|Marx|1993|p=265}}}}{{Quote box
| quote = In the Marxian view, human history is like a river. From any given vantage point, a river looks much the same day after day. But actually it is constantly flowing and changing, crumbling its banks, widening and deepening its channel. The water seen one day is never the same as that seen the next. Some of it is constantly being evaporated and drawn up, to return as rain. From year to year these changes may be scarcely perceptible. But one day, when the banks are thoroughly weakened and the rains long and heavy, the river floods, bursts its banks, and may take a new course. This represents the dialectical part of Marx's famous theory of dialectical (or historical) materialism.
| source = Hubert Kay, Life, 1948[24]
| width = 30%
| align = right
}}

Historical materialism builds upon the idea of historical progress that became popular in philosophy during the Enlightenment, which asserted that the development of human society has progressed through a series of stages, from hunting and gathering, through pastoralism and cultivation, to commercial society.{{sfn|Meek|1976}} Historical materialism rests on a foundation of metaphysical materialism, in which matter is considered primary and ideas, thought, and consciousness are secondary, i.e. consciousness and human ideas about the universe result from material conditions rather than vice versa.[25]

Historical materialism springs from a fundamental underlying reality of human existence: that in order for subsequent generations of human beings to survive, it is necessary for them to produce and reproduce the material requirements of everyday life.{{sfn|Seligman|1901|p=163}} Marx then extended this premise by asserting the importance of the fact that, in order to carry out production and exchange, people have to enter into very definite social relations, or more specifically, "relations of production". However, production does not get carried out in the abstract, or by entering into arbitrary or random relations chosen at will, but instead are determined by the development of the existing forces of production.[26] How production is accomplished depends on the character of society's productive forces, which refers to the means of production such as the tools, instruments, technology, land, raw materials, and human knowledge and abilities in terms of using these means of production. [27] The relations of production are determined by the level and character of these productive forces present at any given time in history. In all societies, Human beings collectively work on nature but, especially in class societies, do not do the same work. In such societies, there is a division of labour in which people not only carry out different kinds of labour but occupy different social positions on the basis of those differences. The most important such division is that between manual and intellectual labour whereby one class produces a given society's wealth while another is able to monopolize control the means of production and so both governs that society and lives off of the wealth generated by the labouring classes.[28]

Marx identified society's relations of production (arising on the basis of given productive forces) as the economic base of society. He also explained that on the foundation of the economic base there arise certain political institutions, laws, customs, culture, etc., and ideas, ways of thinking, morality, etc. These constitute the political/ideological "superstructure" of society. This superstructure not only has its origin in the economic base, but its features also ultimately correspond to the character and development of that economic base, i.e. the way people organize society, its relations of production, and its mode of production.[9] G.A. Cohen argues in A Defence that a society’s superstructure stabilizes or entrenches its economic structure, but that the economic base is primary and the superstructure secondary. That said, it is precisely because the superstructure strongly affects the base that the base selects that superstructure. As Charles Taylor puts it, "These two directions of influence are so far from being rivals that they are actually complementary. The functional explanation requires that the secondary factor tend to have a causal effect on the primary, for this dispositional fact is the key feature of the explanation."[29] It is because the influences in the two directions are not symmetrical that it makes sense to speak of primary and secondary factors, even where one is giving a non-reductionist, "holistic" account of social interaction.

To summarize, history develops in accordance with the following observations:

  1. Social progress is driven by progress in the material, productive forces a society has at its disposal (technology, labour, capital goods, etc.)
  2. Humans are inevitably involved in productive relations (roughly speaking, economic relationships or institutions), which constitute our most decisive social relations. These relations progress with the development of the productive forces. They are largely determined by the division of labor, which in turn tends to determine social class.
  3. Relations of production are both determined by the means and forces of production and set the conditions of their development. For example, capitalism tends to increase the rate at which the forces develop and stresses the accumulation of capital.
  4. The relations of production define the mode of production. E.g. the capitalist mode of production is characterized by the polarization of society into capitalists and workers.
  5. The superstructure—the cultural and institutional features of a society, its ideological materials—is ultimately an expression of the mode of production on which the society is founded.
  6. Every type of state is a powerful institution of the ruling class; the state is an instrument which one class uses to secure its rule and enforce its preferred relations of production (and its exploitation) onto society.{{citation needed|date=December 2018}}
  7. State power is usually only transferred from one class to another by social and political upheaval.{{citation needed|date=December 2018}}
  8. When a given relations of relations no longer supports further progress in the productive forces, either further progress is strangled, or 'revolution' must occur.{{citation needed|date=December 2018}}
  9. The actual historical process is not predetermined but depends on the class struggle, especially the organization and consciousness of the working class.{{citation needed|date=December 2018}}

Key implications in the study and understanding of history

Many writers note that historical materialism represented a revolution in human thought, and a break from previous ways of understanding the underlying basis of change within various human societies. As Marx puts it, "a coherence arises in human history"{{sfn|Marx|Engels|1968|p=660}} because each generation inherits the productive forces developed previously and in turn further develops them before passing them on to the next generation. Further, this coherence increasingly involves more of humanity the more the productive forces develop and expand to bind people together in production and exchange.

This understanding counters the notion that human history is simply a series of accidents, either without any underlying cause or caused by supernatural beings or forces exerting their will on society. Historical materialism posits that history is made as a result of struggle between different social classes rooted in the underlying economic base. According to G.A. Cohen, author of A Defence, the level of development of society’s productive forces (i.e., society’s technological powers, including tools, machinery, raw materials, and labour power) determines society’s economic structure, in the sense that it selects a structure of economic relations that tends best to facilitate further technological growth. In historical explanation, the overall primacy of the productive forces can be understood in terms of two key theses:

{{cquote|(a) The productive forces tend to develop throughout history (the Development Thesis).
(b) The nature of the production relations of a society is explained by the level of development of its productive forces (the Primacy Thesis proper).[30]}}

In saying that productive forces have a universal tendency to develop, Cohen’s reading of Marx is not claiming that productive forces always develop or that they never decline. Their development may be temporarily blocked, but because human beings have a rational interest in developing their capacities to control their interactions with external nature in order to satisfy their wants, the historical tendency is strongly toward further development of these capacities.

Broadly, the importance of the study of history lies in the ability of history to explain the present. John Bellamy Foster asserts that historical materialism is important in explaining history from a scientific perspective, by following the scientific method, as opposed to belief-system theories like creationism and intelligent design, which do not base their beliefs on verifiable facts and hypotheses.{{sfn|Foster|Clark|2008}}

Trajectory of historical development

The main modes of production that Marx identified generally include primitive communism, slave society, feudalism, and capitalism. In each of these social stages, people interacted with nature and production in different ways. Any surplus from that production was distributed differently as well. To Marx, ancient societies (e.g. Rome and Greece) were based on a ruling class of citizens and a class of slaves; feudalism was based on nobles and serfs; and capitalism based on the capitalist class (bourgeoisie) and the working class (proletariat).

Primitive communism

To historical materialists, hunter-gatherer societies, also known as primitive communist societies, were structured so that economic forces and political forces were one and the same. Societies generally did not have a state, property, money, nor social classes. This inherently makes them communist in social relations although primitive in productive forces.

The ancient mode of production

Slave societies, the ancient mode of production, were formed as productive forces advanced, namely due to agriculture and the abandonment of nomadic society. Slave societies were marked by their use of slavery and minor private property; production for use was the primary form of production. Slave society is considered by historical materialists to be the first class society formed of citizens and slaves. Surplus was distributed to the citizens, which exploited the slaves.[31]

The feudal mode of production

The feudal mode of production emerged from slave society (e.g. in Europe after the collapse of the Roman Empire), coinciding with the further advance of productive forces. Feudal society's class relations were marked by an entrenched nobility and serfdom. Simple commodity production existed in the form of artisans and merchants. This class would grow in size and eventually form the bourgeoisie. Despite this, production was still largely for use.

The capitalist mode of production

The capitalist mode of production materialized when the rising bourgeois class grew large enough to institute a shift in the productive forces. The bourgeoisie's primary form of production was in the form of commodities, i.e. they produced with the purpose of exchanging their products. As this commodity production grew, the old feudal systems came into conflict with the new capitalist ones; feudalism was then eschewed as capitalism emerged. The Bourgeoisie's influence expanded until commodity production became fully generalized.

The feudal system of industry, in which industrial production was monopolised by closed guilds, now no longer sufficed for the growing wants of the new markets. The manufacturing system took its place. The guild-masters were pushed on one side by the manufacturing middle class; division of labour between the different corporate guilds vanished in the face of division of labour in each single workshop.[32]

With the rise of the bourgeoisie came the concepts of nation-states and nationalism. Marx argued that capitalism completely separated the economic and political forces. Marx took the state to be a sign of this separation — it existed to manage the massive conflicts of interest which arose between the proletariat and bourgeoisie in capitalist society. Marx observed that nations arose at the time of the appearance of capitalism on the basis of community of economic life, territory, language, certain features of psychology, and traditions of everyday life and culture. In the Communist Manifesto Marx and Engels explained that the coming into existence of nation-states was the result of class struggle, specifically of the capitalist class's attempts to overthrow the institutions of the former ruling class. Prior to capitalism, nations were not the primary political form.[33] Vladimir Lenin shared a similar view on nation-states.[34] There were two opposite tendencies in the development of nations under capitalism. One of them wass expressed in the activation of national life and national movements against the oppressors. The other was expressed in the expansion of links among nations, the breaking down of barriers between them, the establishment of a unified economy and of a world market (globalization); the first is a characteristic of lower-stage capitalism and the second a more advanced form, furthering the unity of the international proletariat.{{sfn|Lenin|n.d.}} Alongside this development was the forced removal of the serfdom from the countryside to the city, forming a new proletarian class. This caused the countryside to become reliant on large cities. Subsequently, the new capitalist mode of production also began expanding into other societies that had not yet developed a capitalist system (e.g. the scramble for Africa).

National differences and antagonism between peoples are daily more and more vanishing, owing to the development of the bourgeoisie, to freedom of commerce, to the world market, to uniformity in the mode of production and in the conditions of life corresponding thereto.

The supremacy of the proletariat will cause them to vanish still faster. United action, of the leading civilised countries at least, is one of the first conditions for the emancipation of the proletariat.

In proportion as the exploitation of one individual by another will also be put an end to, the exploitation of one nation by another will also be put an end to. In proportion as the antagonism between classes within the nation vanishes, the hostility of one nation to another will come to an end.[35]

Under capitalism, the Bourgeoisie and Proletariat become the two primary classes. Class struggle between these two classes was now prevalent. With the emergence of capitalism, productive forces were now able to flourish, causing the industrial revolution in Europe. Despite this, however, the productive forces eventually reach a point where they can no longer expand, causing the same collapse that occurred at the end of feudalism:

Modern bourgeois society, with its relations of production, of exchange and of property, a society that has conjured up such gigantic means of production and of exchange, is like the sorcerer who is no longer able to control the powers of the nether world whom he has called up by his spells. [...] The productive forces at the disposal of society no longer tend to further the development of the conditions of bourgeois property; on the contrary, they have become too powerful for these conditions, by which they are fettered, and so soon as they overcome these fetters, they bring disorder into the whole of bourgeois society, endanger the existence of bourgeois property.[36]

The communist mode of production

The lower-stage of communism

The bourgeoisie, as Marx stated in the Communist Manifesto, has "forged the weapons that bring death to itself; it has also called into existence the men who are to wield those weapons — the modern working class — the proletarians."[37] Historical materialists henceforth believe that the modern proletariat are the new revolutionary class in relation to the bourgeoisie, in the same way that the bourgeoisie was the revolutionary class in relation to the nobility under feudalism.[38] The proletariat, then, must seize power as the new revolutionary class in a dictatorship of the proletariat.

Between capitalist and communist society there lies the period of the revolutionary transformation of the one into the other. Corresponding to this is also a political transition period in which the state can be nothing but the revolutionary dictatorship of the proletariat.[39]

Marx also describes a communist society developed alongside the proletarian dictatorship:

Within the co-operative society based on common ownership of the means of production, the producers do not exchange their products; just as little does the labor employed on the products appear here as the value of these products, as a material quality possessed by them, since now, in contrast to capitalist society, individual labor no longer exists in an indirect fashion but directly as a component part of total labor. The phrase "proceeds of labor", objectionable also today on account of its ambiguity, thus loses all meaning.

What we have to deal with here is a communist society, not as it has developed on its own foundations, but, on the contrary, just as it emerges from capitalist society; which is thus in every respect, economically, morally, and intellectually, still stamped with the birthmarks of the old society from whose womb it emerges. Accordingly, the individual producer receives back from society – after the deductions have been made – exactly what he gives to it. What he has given to it is his individual quantum of labor. For example, the social working day consists of the sum of the individual hours of work; the individual labor time of the individual producer is the part of the social working day contributed by him, his share in it. He receives a certificate from society that he has furnished such-and-such an amount of labor (after deducting his labor for the common funds); and with this certificate, he draws from the social stock of means of consumption as much as the same amount of labor cost. The same amount of labor which he has given to society in one form, he receives back in another.[40]

This lower-stage of communist society is, according to Marx, analogous to the lower-stage of capitalist society, i.e. the transition from feudalism to capitalism, in that both societies are "stamped with the birthmarks of the old society from whose womb it emerges." The emphasis on the idea that modes of production do not exist in isolation but rather are materialized from the previous existence is a core idea in historical materialism.

There is considerable debate among communists regarding the nature of this society. Some such as Joseph Stalin, Fidel Castro, and other Marxist-Leninists believe that the lower-stage of communism constitutes its own mode of production, which they call socialist rather than communist. Marxist-Leninists believe that this society may still maintain the concepts of property, money, and commodity production.[41] Other communists argue that the lower-stage of communism is just that; a communist mode of production, without commodities or money, stamped with the birthmarks of capitalism.

The higher-stage of communism

To Marx, the higher-stage of communist society is a free association of producers which has successfully negated all remnants of capitalism, notably the concepts of states, nationality, sexism, families, alienation, social classes, money, property, commodities, the bourgeoisie, the proletariat, division of labor, cities and countryside, class struggle, religion, universal truths, morality, and markets. It is the negation of capitalism.[42][43]

Marx made the following comments on the higher-phase of communist society:

In a higher phase of communist society, after the enslaving subordination of the individual to the division of labor, and therewith also the antithesis between mental and physical labor, has vanished; after labor has become not only a means of life but life's prime want; after the productive forces have also increased with the all-around development of the individual, and all the springs of co-operative wealth flow more abundantly – only then can the narrow horizon of bourgeois right be crossed in its entirety and society inscribe on its banners: From each according to his ability, to each according to his needs![44]

Warnings against misuse

{{See also|Economic determinism}}

In the 1872 Preface to the French edition of Das Kapital Vol. 1, Marx emphasized that "There is no royal road to science, and only those who do not dread the fatiguing climb of its steep paths have a chance of gaining its luminous summits."[45] Reaching a scientific understanding required conscientious, painstaking research, instead of philosophical speculation and unwarranted, sweeping generalizations. Having abandoned abstract philosophical speculation in his youth, Marx himself showed great reluctance during the rest of his life about offering any generalities or universal truths about human existence or human history.

Marx himself took care to indicate that he was only proposing a guideline to historical research (Leitfaden or Auffassung), and was not providing any substantive "theory of history" or "grand philosophy of history", let alone a "master-key to history". Engels expressed irritation with dilettante academics who sought to knock up their skimpy historical knowledge as quickly as possible into some grand theoretical system that would explain "everything" about history. He opined that historical materialism and the theory of modes of production was being used as an excuse for not studying history.[46]

The first explicit and systematic summary of the materialist interpretation of history published was Engels's book Herr Eugen Dühring's Revolution in Science, written with Marx's approval and guidance, and often referred to as the Anti-Dühring. One of the polemic's was to ridicule the easy "world schematism" of philosophers, who invented the latest wisdom from behind their writing desks. Towards the end of his life, in 1877, Marx wrote a letter to the editor of the Russian paper Otetchestvennye Zapisky, which significantly contained the following disclaimer:

{{Quotation|... If Russia is tending to become a capitalist nation after the example of the Western European countries, and during the last years she has been taking a lot of trouble in this direction—she will not succeed without having first transformed a good part of her peasants into proletarians; and after that, once taken to the bosom of the capitalist regime, she will experience its pitiless laws like other profane peoples. That is all. But that is not enough for my critic. He feels himself obliged to metamorphose my historical sketch of the genesis of capitalism in Western Europe into an historico-philosophic theory of the marche generale imposed by fate upon every people, whatever the historic circumstances in which it finds itself, in order that it may ultimately arrive at the form of economy which will ensure, together with the greatest expansion of the productive powers of social labor, the most complete development of man. But I beg his pardon. (He is both honouring and shaming me too much.)[47]}}

Marx goes on to illustrate how the same factors can in different historical contexts produce very different results, so that quick and easy generalizations are not really possible. To indicate how seriously Marx took research, when he died, his estate contained several cubic metres of Russian statistical publications (it was, as the old Marx observed, in Russia that his ideas gained most influence).

But what is true is that insofar as Marx and Engels regarded historical processes as law-governed processes, the possible future directions of historical development were to a great extent limited and conditioned by what happened before. Retrospectively, historical processes could be understood to have happened by necessity in certain ways and not others, and to some extent at least, the most likely variants of the future could be specified on the basis of careful study of the known facts.

Towards the end of his life, Engels commented several times about the abuse of historical materialism.

In a letter to Conrad Schmidt dated 5 August 1890, he stated:

{{Quotation|And if this man (i.e., Paul Barth) has not yet discovered that while the material mode of existence is the primum agens this does not preclude the ideological spheres from reacting upon it in their turn, though with a secondary effect, he cannot possibly have understood the subject he is writing about. (...) The materialist conception of history has a lot of [dangerous friends] nowadays, to whom it serves as an excuse for not studying history. Just as Marx used to say, commenting on the French "Marxists" of the late 70s: "All I know is that I am not a Marxist." (...) In general, the word "materialistic" serves many of the younger writers in Germany as a mere phrase with which anything and everything is labeled without further study, that is, they stick on this label and then consider the question disposed of. But our conception of history is above all a guide to study, not a lever for construction after the manner of the Hegelian. All history must be studied afresh, the conditions of existence of the different formations of society must be examined individually before the attempt is made to deduce them from the political, civil law, aesthetic, philosophic, religious, etc., views corresponding to them. Up to now but little has been done here because only a few people have got down to it seriously. In this field we can utilize heaps of help, it is immensely big, anyone who will work seriously can achieve much and distinguish himself. But instead of this too many of the younger Germans simply make use of the phrase historical materialism (and everything can be turned into a phrase) only in order to get their own relatively scanty historical knowledge – for economic history is still in its swaddling clothes! – constructed into a neat system as quickly as possible, and they then deem themselves something very tremendous. And after that a Barth can come along and attack the thing itself, which in his circle has indeed been degraded to a mere phrase.[48]}}

Finally, in a letter to Franz Mehring dated 14 July 1893, Engels stated:

{{Quotation|... there is only one other point lacking, which, however, Marx and I always failed to stress enough in our writings and in regard to which we are all equally guilty. That is to say, we all laid, and were bound to lay, the main emphasis, in the first place, on the derivation of political, juridical and other ideological notions, and of actions arising through the medium of these notions, from basic economic facts. But in so doing we neglected the formal side – the ways and means by which these notions, etc., come about – for the sake of the content. This has given our adversaries a welcome opportunity for misunderstandings, of which Paul Barth is a striking example.[49]}}

Criticisms

Philosopher of science Karl Popper, in The Poverty of Historicism and Conjectures and Refutations, critiqued such claims of the explanatory power or valid application of historical materialism by arguing that it could explain or explain away any fact brought before it, making it unfalsifiable and thus pseudoscientific. Similar arguments were brought by Leszek Kołakowski in Main Currents of Marxism.{{sfnm |1a1=Kołakowski |1y=1978 |2a1=Popper |2y=1957}}

In his 1940 essay Theses on the Philosophy of History, scholar Walter Benjamin compares historical materialism to the Turk, an 18th-century device which was promoted as a mechanized automaton which could defeat skilled chess players but actually concealed a human who controlled the machine. Benjamin suggested that, despite Marx's claims to scientific objectivity, historical materialism was actually quasi-religious. Like the Turk, wrote Benjamin, "[t]he puppet called 'historical materialism' is always supposed to win. It can do this with no further ado against any opponent, so long as it employs the services of theology, which as everyone knows is small and ugly and must be kept out of sight." Benjamin's friend and colleague Gershom Scholem would argue that Benjamin's critique of historical materialism was so definitive that, as Mark Lilla would write, "nothing remains of historical materialism ... but the term itself".[50] However, Benjamin was arguing against a mechanistic form of historical materialist explanation then prevalent in Stalin's Russia, and was himself a committed, if unorthodox, Marxist. Later in "On the Concept of History", he writes:

{{quote|Class struggle, which for a historian schooled in Marx is always in evidence, is a fight for the crude and material things without which no refined and spiritual things could exist. ... There is no document of culture which is not at the same time a document of barbarism. And just as such a document is never free of barbarism, so barbarism taints the manner in which it was transmitted from one hand to another. The historical materialist therefore dissociates himself from this process of transmission as far as possible. He regards it as his task to brush history against the grain.{{sfn|Benjamin}}}}

See also

{{Wikiquote}}{{Portal|History|Social and political philosophy}}
  • Analytical Marxism
  • Classical Marxism
  • Economic determinism
  • Formalist–substantivist debate
  • Fundamentals of Marxism–Leninism
  • Orthodox Marxism
  • Parametric determinism
  • Technological determinism
  • Theory of historical trajectory

References

Footnotes

1. ^{{Cite web|url=https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1845/german-ideology/ch01b.htm|title=The German Ideology|last=Marx|first=Karl|date=1845|website=www.marxists.org|archive-url=|archive-date=|dead-url=|access-date=2019-03-05}}
2. ^{{cite book |last1=Marx |first1=Karl |title=The German Ideology |date=1845 |accessdate=12 March 2019 |url=https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1845/german-ideology/ch01a.htm}}
3. ^{{cite book |last1=Marx |first1=Karl |title=The German Ideology |date=1845 |accessdate=12 March 2019|url=https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1845/german-ideology/ch01a.htm}}
4. ^{{cite book |last1=Marx |first1=Karl |title=The German Ideology |date=1845 |accessdate=12 March 2019|url=https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1845/german-ideology/ch01a.htm}}
5. ^{{cite web |last=Woods |first=Alan |year=2016 |title=What Is Historical Materialism? |url=http://www.marxist.com/an-introduction-to-historical-materialism.htm |website=In Defence of Marxism |publisher=International Marxist Tendency |access-date=28 November 2017}}
6. ^{{cite web |url=https://marxists.catbull.com/archive/marx/works/1880/soc-utop/ch03.htm |title= Socialism: Utopian and Scientific |author= Friedrich Engels |website=marxists.org |publisher=Marxists Internet Archive |access-date=2018-09-06}}
7. ^{{cite web |url=https://marxists.catbull.com/archive/marx/works/1880/05/04.htm |title=Introduction to the French Edition of Engels' Socialism: Utopian and Scientific |author=Karl Marx |website=marxists.org |publisher= Marxists Internet Archive| access-date=2018-09-06}}
8. ^{{cite web |author=Frederick Engels |url=http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1880/soc-utop/int-mat.htm |title=Socialism: Utopian and Scientific (Introduction - Materialism) |publisher=Marxists Internet Archive |access-date=7 December 2011}}
9. ^{{cite web |url=https://plato.stanford.edu/entries/marx/ |title=Karl Marx (Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy) |website=Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy |publisher=The Metaphysics Research Lab, Center for the Study of Language and Information (CSLI), Stanford University |access-date=2018-09-06}}
10. ^{{cite book|last=Althusser |first=Louis |title=For Marx |publisher= The Penguin Press |date=1969 |page=59 |url=http://www.marx2mao.com/Other/FM65NB.html}}
11. ^{{cite web|url= https://plato.stanford.edu/entries/max-stirner/ |title=Max Stirner (Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy) |website=Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy |publisher=The Metaphysics Research Lab, Center for the Study of Language and Information (CSLI), Stanford University |access-date=2018-09-06}}
12. ^{{cite book |last=Welsh |first=John F. |title=Max Stirner's Dialectical Egoism, A new interpretation |pages=20–23 |publisher=Lexington Books |date=2010}}
13. ^{{cite web|url=https://www.marxists.org/archive/fromm/works/1961/man/ch02.htm|title=Marx's Conception of Man |author= Erich Fromm |publisher=Marxists.org|accessdate=2018-09-06}}
14. ^{{cite web |url=https://www.marxists.org/reference/archive/stalin/works/1938/09.htm |title= Dialectical and Historical Materialism |author= Joseph Stalin |website=marxists.org |publisher= Marxists Internet Archive| access-date=2018-09-06}}
15. ^{{cite book|author=Polanyi, K.|title=The Great Transformation | location=New York|year=1944| pages=44–49}}
16. ^{{cite book|title=ibid. |pages=41}}
17. ^{{Cite book|last=Hann |first=Chris |title=Economic Anthropology (The International Encyclopedia of Anthropology) |pages = 1–16|publisher=John Wiley & Sons, 2018 |date=2017-09-29|doi=10.1002/9781118924396.wbiea2194 |chapter = Economic Anthropology|isbn = 9780470657225}}
18. ^G. A. Cohen, Karl Marx’s Theory of History (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1978), p. x.
19. ^{{cite journal |last1=Habermas |first1=Jürgen |date=Autumn 1975 |title=Toward a Reconstruction of Historical Materialism |url=https://www.unige.ch/sciences-societe/socio/files/3514/0533/6053/Habermas_1975.pdf |journal=Theory and Society |volume=2 |issue=3 |pages=287-300 |doi= |access-date=2018-12-05 }}
20. ^{{cite book|title=Science, Class and Society: on the formation of Sociology and Historical Materialism |last= Therborn |first=Göran |publisher= London: Verso Books |date=1980}}
21. ^{{cite book|first1=Paul |last1=Hirst |first2=Barry |last2= Hindess |title=Pre-Capitalist Modes of Production | location=London |publisher=Routledge & Kegan Paul |year=1975 |pages=}}
22. ^{{cite book|first1=Bob |last1=Jessop |editor1-last=Brown |editor1-first=A |editor2-last=Fleetwood |editor2-first=S |editor3-last=Roberts |editor3-first=J |chapter=Capitalism, the Regulation Approach, and Critical Realism |title=Critical Realism and Marxism | location=London |publisher=Routledge |year=2001 |pages=}}
23. ^{{cite news |last=Douglas |first=Angus |date=2015-12-16 |title=Marxism versus Spiral Dynamics Integral |url=https://www.news24.com/MyNews24/marxism-versus-spiral-dynamics-integral-20151116 |work=News24 |location=South Africa |access-date=2018-12-05}}
24. ^{{cite magazine |last=Kay |first=Hubert |date=18 October 1948 |title=Karl Marx |magazine=Life |page=66}}
25. ^{{Cite web |url=https://www.britannica.com/topic/materialism-philosophy |title=Materialism |website=britannica.com |publisher=Encyclopedia Britannica, Inc. |last=Carswell Smart |first=John Jamieson |date= |accessdate=December 5, 2018}}
26. ^{{cite book |last=Marx |first=Karl |date=1999 |title=Capital: Critique of Political Economy |volume=3 |chapter=48 |url=https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1867-c1/p2.htm |publisher=Marxists Internet Archive |accessdate=2018-12-05}}
27. ^{{cite book|url=https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1847/poverty-philosophy/ch02.htm|title=The Poverty of Philosophy|last=Marx|first=Karl|date=1999|publisher=Marxists Internet Archive|location=marxists.org|chapter=2|accessdate=2018-12-05}}
28. ^{{Cite book|title=The Revolutionary Ideas of Karl Marx|last=Callinicos|first=Alex|publisher=Haymarket Books|year=2011|isbn=|location=Chicago|pages=99}}
29. ^Charles Taylor, “Critical Notice”, Canadian Journal of Philosophy 10 (1980), p. 330.
30. ^Cohen, p. 134.
31. ^{{cite book |last1=Harman |first1=C |title=A People's History of the World |publisher=Bookmarks}}
32. ^{{cite book |last1=Marx |first1=Karl |title=The Communist Manifesto |date=1848 |location=London |url=https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1848/communist-manifesto/ch01.htm#007 |accessdate=12 March 2019}}
33. ^{{cite web |last=Dixon |first=Norm |title=Marx, Engels and Lenin on the National Question |url=http://links.org.au/node/164 |website=Links International Journal of Socialist Renewal |access-date=21 April 2018}}
34. ^{{cite web |title=В.И. Ленин. О национальном вопросе и национальной политике |url=http://leninism.su/works/115-conspect/4248-v-i-lenin-o-natsionalnom-voprose-i-natsionalnoj-politike.html?showall= |language=ru |access-date=21 April 2018}}
35. ^{{cite book |last1=Marx |first1=Karl |title=The Communist Manifesto |date=1848 |location=London |url=https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1848/communist-manifesto/ch01.htm#007 |accessdate=4 April 2019}}
36. ^{{cite book |last1=Marx |first1=Karl |title=The Communist Manifesto |date=1848 |location=London |url=https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1848/communist-manifesto/ch01.htm#007 |accessdate=12 March 2019}}
37. ^{{cite book |last1=Marx |first1=Karl |title=The Communist Manifesto |date=1848 |location=London |url=https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1848/communist-manifesto/ch01.htm#007 |accessdate=12 March 2019}}
38. ^{{cite book |last1=Marx |first1=Karl |title=Critique of the Gotha Programme |url=https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1875/gotha/ch04.htm |accessdate=12 March 2019}}
39. ^{{cite book |last1=Marx |first1=Karl |title=Critique of the Gotha Programme |url=https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1875/gotha/ch04.htm |accessdate=12 March 2019}}
40. ^{{cite book |last1=Marx |first1=Karl |title=Critique of the Gotha Programme |url=https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1875/gotha/ch01.htm |accessdate=12 March 2019}}
41. ^{{cite book |last1=Stalin |first1=Joseph |title=Economic Problems of Socialism in the USSR |url=https://www.marxists.org/reference/archive/stalin/works/1951/economic-problems/index.htm |accessdate=12 March 2019}}
42. ^{{cite book |last1=Marx |first1=Karl |title=The Communist Manifesto |date=1848 |location=London |url=https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1848/communist-manifesto/ch02.htm#007 |accessdate=12 March 2019}}
43. ^{{cite book |last1=Marx |first1=Karl |title=The German Ideology |date=1845 |accessdate=12 March 2019|url=https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1845/german-ideology/ch01a.htm}}
44. ^{{cite book |last1=Marx |first1=Karl |title=Critique of the Gotha Programme |url=https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1875/gotha/ch01.htm |accessdate=12 March 2019}}
45. ^{{cite book |last=Marx |first=Karl |date=1999 |title=Capital: Critique of Political Economy |volume=1 |chapter=Preface |url=https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1894-c3/ch48.htm |location=marxists.org |publisher=Marxists Internet Archive |accessdate=2018-12-05}}
46. ^Engels, cited approvingly by E. P. Thompson in '[https://www.marxists.org/archive/thompson-ep/1965/english.htm The peculiarities of the English],' Socialist Register, 1965.
47. ^{{cite web |url=https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1877/11/russia.htm |title=Letter from Marx to Editor of the Otecestvenniye Zapisky |publisher=Marxists Internet Archive |access-date=10 November 2018}}
48. ^{{cite web |url=http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1890/letters/90_08_05.htm |title=Letters: Marx–Engels Correspondence 1890 |publisher=Marxists Internet Archive |access-date=7 December 2011}}
49. ^{{cite web |url=http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1893/letters/93_07_14.htm |title=Letters: Marx–Engels Correspondence 1893 |publisher=Marxists Internet Archive |access-date=7 December 2011}}
50. ^{{cite magazine |last=Lilla |first=Mark |author-link=Mark Lilla |date=25 May 1995 |title=The Riddle of Walter Benjamin |magazine=The New York Review of Books}}

Bibliography

{{refbegin|35em|indent=yes}}

{{cite book


|last=Benjamin
|first=Walter
|author-link=Walter Benjamin
|title=Theses on the Philosophy of History
|ref=harv
|title-link=Theses on the Philosophy of History
}}

{{cite book


|last=Cohen
|first=G. A.
|author-link=Gerald Cohen
|year=2000
|orig-year=1978
|title=Karl Marx's Theory of History: A Defence
|edition=expanded
|location=Oxford
|publisher=Clarendon Press
|ref=harv
|title-link=Karl Marx's Theory of History: A Defence
}}

{{cite book


|last=Engels
|first=Friedrich
|author-link=Friedrich Engels
|year=1946
|chapter=Foreward
|chapter-url=https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1886/ludwig-feuerbach/foreword.htm
|title=Ludwig Feuerbach and the End of Classical German Philosophy
|url=https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1886/ludwig-feuerbach/index.htm
|location=Moscow
|publisher=Progress Publishers
|access-date=21 April 2018
|via=Marxists Internet Archive
|ref=harv
}}

{{cite book


|last=Foster
|first=John Bellamy
|author-link=John Bellamy Foster
|year=1999
|title=Marx's Ecology: Materialism and Nature
|location=New York
|publisher=Monthly Review Press
|ref=harv
}}

{{cite book


|last1=Foster
|first1=John Bellamy
|author1-link=John Bellamy Foster
|last2=Clark
|first2=Brett
|author2-link=Brett Clark (sociologist)
|year=2008
|title=Critique of Intelligent Design: Materialism versus Creationism from Antiquity to the Present
|location=New York
|publisher=Monthly Review Press
|isbn=978-1-58367-173-3
|ref=harv
}}

{{cite book


|last=Fromm
|first=Erich
|author-link=Erich Fromm
|year=1961
|chapter=Marx's Historical Materialism
|chapter-url=https://www.marxists.org/archive/fromm/works/1961/man/ch02.htm
|title=Marx's Concept of Man
|location=New York
|publisher=Frederick Ungar Publishing
|access-date=21 April 2018
|via=Marxists Internet Archive
|ref=harv
|title-link=Marx's Concept of Man
}}

{{cite book


|last=Kołakowski
|first=Leszek
|author-link=Leszek Kołakowski
|year=1978
|title=Main Currents of Marxism: Its Origins, Growth and Dissolution
|ref=harv
|title-link=Main Currents of Marxism
}}

{{cite book


|last=Lenin
|first=Vladimir Illyich
|author-link=Vladimir Lenin
|year=n.d.
|chapter=Критические заметки по национальному вопросу
|trans-chapter=Critical Remarks on the National Question
|title=Полного собрания сочинений В. И. Ленина
|language=ru
|volume=24
|edition=5th
|pages=113–150
|ref=harv
}}

{{cite book


|contributor-last=Marx
|contributor-first=Karl
|contributor-link=Karl Marx
|last=Marx
|first=Karl
|author-link=Karl Marx
|year=1977
|contribution=Preface
|contribution-url=https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1859/critique-pol-economy/preface.htm
|editor-last=Dobb
|editor-first=Maurice
|editor-link=Maurice Dobb
|title=A Contribution to the Critique of Political Economy
|translator-last=Ryazanskaya
|translator-first=S. W.
|location=Moscow
|publisher=Progress Publishers
|access-date=21 April 2018
|via=Marxists Internet Archive
|ref=harv
|title-link=A Contribution to the Critique of Political Economy
}}

{{cite book


|last=Marx
|first=Karl
|author-link=Karl Marx
|author-mask={{long dash}}
|year=1993
|title=Grundrisse: Foundations of the Critique of Political Economy
|translator-last=Nicolaus
|translator-first=Martin
|location=London
|publisher=Penguin Books
|isbn=978-0-14-044575-6
|ref=harv
|title-link=Grundrisse
}}

{{cite book


|last1=Marx
|first1=Karl
|author1-link=Karl Marx
|last2=Engels
|first2=Friedrich
|year=1968
|title=Selected Works in One Volume
|location=London
|publisher=Lawrence and Wishart
|ref=harv
}}

{{cite book


|last=Meek
|first=Ronald L.
|author-link=Ronald L. Meek
|year=1976
|title=Social Science and the Ignoble Savage
|series=Cambridge Studies in the History and Theory of Politics
|location=Cambridge, England
|publisher=Cambridge University Press
|ref=harv
}}

{{cite book


|last=Popper
|first=Karl
|author-link=Karl Popper
|year=1957
|title=The Poverty of Historicism
|ref=harv
|title-link=The Poverty of Historicism
}}

{{cite journal


|last=Seligman
|first=Edwin R. A.
|author-link=Edwin Robert Anderson Seligman
|year=1901
|title=The Economic Interpretation of History
|journal=Political Science Quarterly
|volume=16
|number=4
|pages=612–640
|doi=10.2307/2140420
|doi-access=free
|ref=harv
|jstor=2140420
}}

{{cite journal


|last=Thompson
|first=E. P.
|author-link=E. P. Thompson
|year=1965
|title=The Peculiarities of the English
|url=http://www.socialistregister.com/index.php/srv/article/view/5963
|journal=Socialist Register
|volume=2
|pages=311–362
|access-date=21 April 2018
|ref=harv
}}{{refend}}

Further reading

{{further reading cleanup|date=April 2018}}{{refbegin|35em|indent=yes}}

{{cite book


|last=Acton
|first=H. B.
|author-link=H. B. Acton
|title=The Illusion of the Epoch

}}
Critical account which focusses on incoherencies in the thought of Marx, Engels and Lenin.

{{cite book


|last=Anderson
|first=Perry
|year=1974
|title=Lineages of the Absolutist State
}}

{{cite book


|last=Aronowitz
|first=Stanley
|author-link=Stanley Aronowitz
|year=1981
|title=The Crisis in Historical Materialism

}}
American criticism of orthodox Marxism and argument for a more radical version of historical materialism that sticks closer to Marx by changing itself to keep up with changes in the historical situation.

{{cite book


|last=Blackledge
|first=Paul
|year=2006
|title=Reflections on the Marxist Theory of History
}}

{{cite book


|last=Blackledge
|first=Paul
|year=2018
|title="Historical Materialism" in Oxford Handbook on Karl Marx|url= http://www.oxfordhandbooks.com/view/10.1093/oxfordhb/9780190695545.001.0001/oxfordhb-9780190695545-e-1
|doi=10.1093/oxfordhb/9780190695545.001.0001
}}

{{cite book


|last=Boudin
|first=Louis B.
|author-link=Louis B. Boudin
|year=1907
|title=The Theoretical System of Karl Marx
|location=Chicago
|publisher=Charles H. Kerr Publishing Co.

}}
Contains an early defence of the materialist conception of history against its critics of the day.

{{cite book


|last=Childe
|first=V. Gordon
|author1-link=V. Gordon Childe
|title=Man Makes Himself

}}
Free interpretation of Marx's idea.

{{cite book


|last=Cohen
|first=Gerald
|author-link=Gerald Cohen
|title=Karl Marx's Theory of History: A Defence

}}
Influential analytical Marxist interpretation.

{{cite book


|last=Draper
|first=Hal
|author-link=Hal Draper
|title=Karl Marx's Theory of Revolution

}}
Captures the full subtlety of Marx's thought, but at length in four volumes.

{{cite book


|last=Fleischer
|first=Helmut
|title=Marxism and History

}}
Good reply to false interpretations of Marx's view of history.

{{cite book


|last=Gandler
|first=Stefan
|author-link=Stefan Gandler
|year=2015
|title=Critical Marxism in Mexico: Adolfo Sánchez Vázquez and Bolívar Echeverría
|series=Historical Materialism Book Series
|volume=87
|location=Leiden, Netherlands
|publisher=Brill Academic Press
|isbn=978-90-04-28468-5
|issn=1570-1522
}}

{{cite book


|last=Giddens
|first=Anthony
|author-link=Anthony Giddens
|year=1981
|title=A Contemporary Critique of Historical Materialism
}}

{{cite book


|last=Graham
|first=Loren R.
|author-link=Loren Graham
|title=Science Philosophy and Human Behavior in the Soviet Union

}}
Sympathetically critical of dialectical materialism.

{{cite book


|last=Habermas
|first=Jürgen
|author-link=Jürgen Habermas
|title=Communication and the Evolution of Society

}}
Argues historical materialism must be revised to include communicative action.

{{cite book


|last=Harman
|first=Chris
|author-link=Chris Harman
|title=A People's History of the World

}}
Marxist view of history according to a leader of the International Socialist Tendency.

{{cite journal


|last=Harper
|first=J.
|author-link=Anton Pannekoek
|year=1942
|title=Materialism and Historical Materialism
|url=http://www.marxists.org/archive/pannekoe/materialism/index.htm
|journal=New Essays
|volume=6
|issue=2
|access-date=21 April 2018
|via=Marxists Internet Archive
}}

{{cite book


|last=Holt
|first=Justin P.
|year=2014
|title=The Social Thought of Karl Marx
|location=Los Angeles
|publisher=SAGE Publications
|isbn=978-1-4129-9784-3
|doi=10.4135/9781483349381

}}
Provides an introductory chapter on historical materialism.

{{cite book


|last=Jakubowski
|first=Franz
|author-link=Franz Jakubowski
|title=Ideology and Superstructure

}}
Attempts to provide an alternative to schematic interpretations of historical materialism.

{{cite book


|last=Jordan
|first=Z. A.
|year=1967
|chapter=The Origins of Dialectical Materialism
|chapter-url=https://marxmyths.org/jordan/article.htm
|title=The Evolution of Dialectical Materialism: A Philosophical and Sociological Analysis
|location=London
|publisher=Macmillan
|access-date=21 April 2018
|via=Marx Myths & Legends

}}
Good survey.

{{cite book


|last=Mandel
|first=Ernest
|author-link=Ernest Mandel
|title=Introduction to Marxism

}}
Emphasizes understanding the roots of class society and the state.

{{cite book


|last=Mandel
|first=Ernest
|author-link=Ernest Mandel
|author-mask={{long dash}}
|year=1986
|title=The Place of Marxism in History
|url=https://www.marxists.org/archive/mandel/19xx/marx-hist/index.htm
|publisher=International Institute for Research and Education
|access-date=21 April 2018
|via=Marxists Internet Archive

}}
Modelled on Lenin's "Three components of Marxism"{{citation needed|date=December 2013}} but with a section on the reception and diffusion of Marxism in the world.

{{cite book


|author=Mao Zedong
|author-link=Mao Zedong
|title=Four Essays on Philosophy

}}
Standard Maoist reading of Marx's materialism.

{{cite book


|last=Marx
|first=Karl
|author-link=Karl Marx
|year=1848
|title=Manifesto of the Communist Party
|title-link=The Communist Manifesto
}}

{{cite book


|last=Marx
|first=Karl
|author-link=Karl Marx
|author-mask={{long dash}}
|year=1869
|title=The Eighteenth Brumaire of Louis Napoleon
|title-link=The Eighteenth Brumaire of Louis Napoleon
}}

{{cite book


|last=Marx
|first=Karl
|author-link=Karl Marx
|author-mask={{long dash}}
|year=1887
|editor-last=Engels
|editor-first=Friedrich
|editor-link=Friedrich Engels
|title=Capital: Critique of Political Economy. Volume I: The Process of Production of Capital
|translator1-last=Moore
|translator1-first=Samuel
|translator2-last=Aveling
|translator2-first=Edward
|translator2-link=Edward Aveling
|location=Moscow
|publisher=Progress Publishers
|title-link=Capital, Volume I
}}

{{cite book


|last=Marx
|first=Karl
|author-link=Karl Marx
|author-mask={{long dash}}
|year=1895
|title=The Class Struggles in France, 1848–1850
|title-link=The Class Struggles in France 1848-1850
}}

{{cite book


|last=Marx
|first=Karl
|author-link=Karl Marx
|author-mask={{long dash}}
|year=1932
|title=Economic and Philosophic Manuscripts of 1844
|title-link=Economic and Philosophic Manuscripts of 1844
}}

{{cite book


|last=Marx
|first=Karl
|author-link=Karl Marx
|author-mask={{long dash}}
|year=1932
|title=The German Ideology
|title-link=The German Ideology
}}

{{cite book


|last=Marx
|first=Karl
|author-link=Karl Marx
|author-mask={{long dash}}
|year=1956
|editor-last=Engels
|editor-first=Friedrich
|editor-link=Friedrich Engels
|title=Capital: Critique of Political Economy. Volume II: The Process of Circulation of Capital
|edition=2nd
|translator-last=Lasker
|translator-first=I.
|location=Moscow
|publisher=Progress Publishers
|title-link=Capital, Volume II
}}

{{cite book


|last=Marx
|first=Karl
|author-link=Karl Marx
|author-mask={{long dash}}
|year=1959
|title=Capital: Critique of Political Economy. Volume III: The Process of Capitalist Production as a Whole
|title-link=Capital, Volume III
}}

{{cite book


|last=Marx
|first=Karl
|author-link=Karl Marx
|author-mask={{long dash}}
|year=1964
|editor-last=Hobsbawm
|editor-first=E. J.
|editor-link=Eric Hobsbawm
|title=Pre-Capitalist Economic Formations
|translator-last=Cohen
|translator-first=Jack
|location=London
|publisher=Lawrence & Wishart
}}

{{cite book


|last=Marx
|first=Karl
|author-link=Karl Marx
|author-mask={{long dash}}
|year=1969
|chapter=Theses on Feuerbach
|title=Marx/Engels Selected Works
|location=Moscow
|publisher=Progress Publishers
|pages=13–15
}}

{{cite book


|last=Mehring
|first=Franz
|author-link=Franz Mehring
|year=1975
|title=On Historical Materialism
|url=https://www.marxists.org/archive/mehring/1893/histmat/index.htm
|translator-last=Archer
|translator-first=Bob
|location=London
|publisher=New Park Press
|access-date=21 April 2018
|via=Marxists Internet Archive

}}
Classic statement by a contemporary and friend of Marx & Engels.

{{cite book


|last=Novack
|first=George
|author-link=George Novack
|year=2002
|title=Understanding History: Marxist Essays
|url=https://www.marxists.org/archive/novack/works/history/index.htm
|location=Chippendale, New South Wales
|publisher=Resistance Books
|isbn=978-1-876646-23-3
|access-date=21 April 2018
|via=Marxists Internet Archive

}}
Trotskyist interpretations of problems of history.

{{cite book


|last=Nowak
|first=Leszek
|author-link=Leszek Nowak
|title=Property and Power: Towards a Non-Marxian Historical Materialism

}}
Attempts to develop a post-Stalinist interpretation of Marx's project.

{{cite book


|last=Rees
|first=John
|author-link=John Rees (activist)
|title=The Algebra of Revolution

}}
Classical Marxist account of the philosophy of Marx, Engels, Lenin, Lukacs, and Trotsky.

{{cite book


|last=Rigby
|first=S. H.
|year=1998
|title=Marxism and History: A Critical Introduction
|edition=2nd
|location=Manchester
|publisher=Manchester University Press
|isbn=978-0-7190-5612-3
}}

{{cite book


|last=Shaw
|first=William H.
|title=Marx's Theory of History

}}
Provides a short survey.

{{cite book


|last=Spirkin
|first=Alexander
|author-link=Alexander Spirkin
|year=1990
|title=Fundamentals of Philosophy
|url=https://archive.org/details/FundamentalsOfPhilosophy_913
|translator-last=Syrovatkin
|translator-first=Sergei
|location=Moscow
|publisher=Progress Publishers
|isbn=978-5-01-002582-3
|access-date=15 January 2011
}}

{{cite book


|last=Stalin
|first=Joseph
|author-link=Joseph Stalin
|title=Dialectical and Historical Materialism
|title-link=Dialectical and Historical Materialism

}}
Classic statement of Stalinist doctrine.

{{cite book


|last=Suchting
|first=Wal
|title=Marx: An Introduction

}}
Includes a good short introduction.

{{cite magazine


|year=1979
|title=The Materialist Conception of History
|url=http://www.worldsocialism.org/spgb/education/study-guides/materialist-conception-history
|magazine=Education Bulletin
|issue=1
|access-date=21 April 2018
}}

{{cite book


|last=Therborn
|first=Göran
|author-link=Göran Therborn
|title=Science, Class and Society

}}
Critical survey of the relationship between sociology and historical materialism.

{{cite journal


|last=Thompson
|first=E. P.
|author-link=E. P. Thompson
|title=The Poverty of Theory

}}
Polemic which ridicules theorists of history who do not actually study history.

{{cite book


|last=Wetter
|first=Gustav A.
|title=Dialectical Materialism: a Historical and Systematic Survey of Philosophy in the Soviet Union

}}
Alternative survey.

{{cite book


|last=Witt-Hansen
|first=Johan
|title=Historical Materialism: The Method, The Theories

}}
Sees historical materialism as a methodology and Das Kapital as an application of the method.

{{cite book


|last=Wood
|first=Allen W.
|author-link=Allen W. Wood
|year=2004
|title=Karl Marx
|edition=2nd
|series=Arguments of the Philosophers
|location=Abingdon, England
|publisher=Routledge
|isbn=978-0-415-31697-2

}}
Delves into misinterpretations of Marx including the substitution of "Historical materialism" by Lenin.

{{refend}}{{Marxist and communist phraseology}}{{Authority control}}{{DEFAULTSORT:Historical Materialism}}

5 : Ideology of the Communist Party of the Soviet Union|Marxist theory|Marxism|Theories of history|Materialism

随便看

 

开放百科全书收录14589846条英语、德语、日语等多语种百科知识,基本涵盖了大多数领域的百科知识,是一部内容自由、开放的电子版国际百科全书。

 

Copyright © 2023 OENC.NET All Rights Reserved
京ICP备2021023879号 更新时间:2024/9/20 18:46:11