请输入您要查询的百科知识:

 

词条 Vector measure
释义

  1. Definitions and first consequences

  2. Examples

  3. The variation of a vector measure

  4. Lyapunov's theorem

  5. References

     Books 

  6. See also

In mathematics, a vector measure is a function defined on a family of sets and taking vector values satisfying certain properties. It is a generalization of the concept of finite measure, which takes nonnegative real values only.

Definitions and first consequences

Given a field of sets and a Banach space , a finitely additive vector measure (or measure, for short) is a function such that for any two disjoint sets and in one has

A vector measure is called countably additive if for any sequence of disjoint sets in such that their union is in it holds that

with the series on the right-hand side convergent in the norm of the Banach space

It can be proved that an additive vector measure is countably additive if and only if for any sequence as above one has

where is the norm on

Countably additive vector measures defined on sigma-algebras are more general than finite measures, finite signed measures, and complex measures, which are countably additive functions taking values respectively on the real interval the set of real numbers, and the set of complex numbers.

Examples

Consider the field of sets made up of the interval together with the family of all Lebesgue measurable sets contained in this interval. For any such set , define

where is the indicator function of Depending on where is declared to take values, we get two different outcomes.

  • viewed as a function from to the Lp-space is a vector measure which is not countably-additive.
  • viewed as a function from to the Lp-space is a countably-additive vector measure.

Both of these statements follow quite easily from the criterion (*) stated above.

The variation of a vector measure

Given a vector measure the variation of is defined as

where the supremum is taken over all the partitions

of into a finite number of disjoint sets, for all in . Here, is the norm on

The variation of is a finitely additive function taking values in It holds that

for any in If is finite, the measure is said to be of bounded variation. One can prove that if is a vector measure of bounded variation, then is countably additive if and only if is countably additive.

Lyapunov's theorem

In the theory of vector measures, Lyapunov's theorem states that the range of a (non-atomic) vector measure is closed and convex.[1][2][3] In fact, the range of a non-atomic vector measure is a zonoid (the closed and convex set that is the limit of a convergent sequence of zonotopes).[2] It is used in economics,[4][5][6] in ("bang–bang") control theory,[1][3][7][11] and in statistical theory.[8]

Lyapunov's theorem has been proved by using the Shapley–Folkman lemma,[9] which has been viewed as a discrete analogue of Lyapunov's theorem.[8][10]

[11]

References

1. ^Kluvánek, I., Knowles, G., Vector Measures and Control Systems, North-Holland Mathematics Studies 20, Amsterdam, 1976.
2. ^{{cite book | last1 = Diestel | first1 = Joe | last2 = Uhl | first2 = Jerry J., Jr. | title = Vector measures | publisher = American Mathematical Society | location = Providence, R.I | year = 1977 | pages = | isbn = 0-8218-1515-6}}
3. ^{{Cite book | title=Functional analysis and control theory: Linear systems|last=Rolewicz |first=Stefan|year=1987| isbn=90-277-2186-6| publisher=D. Reidel Publishing Co.; PWN—Polish Scientific Publishers|oclc=13064804|edition=Translated from the Polish by Ewa Bednarczuk|series=Mathematics and its Applications (East European Series)|location=Dordrecht; Warsaw|volume=29|pages=xvi+524|mr=920371| ref=harv | postscript={{inconsistent citations}}}}
4. ^{{Cite book|last=Roberts|first=John|authorlink=Donald John Roberts|chapter=Large economies|title=Contributions to the New Palgrave|editor=David M. Kreps|editor1-link=David M. Kreps|editor2=John Roberts|editor2-link=Donald John Roberts|editor3=Robert B. Wilson|editor3-link=Robert B. Wilson|date=July 1986|pages=30–35|url=https://gsbapps.stanford.edu/researchpapers/library/RP892.pdf|accessdate=7 February 2011|series=Research paper|volume=892|publisher=Graduate School of Business, Stanford University|location=Palo Alto, CA|id=(Draft of articles for the first edition of New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics)|ref=harv|postscript={{inconsistent citations}}}}
5. ^{{cite journal|authorlink=Robert Aumann|first=Robert J.|last=Aumann|title=Existence of competitive equilibrium in markets with a continuum of traders|journal=Econometrica|volume=34|number=1|date=January 1966|pages=1–17|jstor=1909854 | mr = 191623|doi=10.2307/1909854}} This paper builds on two papers by Aumann:

{{cite journal||title=Markets with a continuum of traders|journal=Econometrica|volume=32|number=1–2|date=January–April 1964|pages=39–50|jstor=1913732 | mr = 172689|doi=10.2307/1913732}}

{{cite journal||title=Integrals of set-valued functions|journal=Journal of Mathematical Analysis and Applications|volume=12|number=1|date=August 1965|pages=1–12|doi=10.1016/0022-247X(65)90049-1|mr=185073}}


6. ^{{cite news|last=Vind|first=Karl|date=May 1964|title=Edgeworth-allocations in an exchange economy with many traders|journal=International Economic Review|volume=5|pages=165–77|number=2|ref=harv|jstor=2525560}} Vind's article was noted by {{harvtxt|Debreu|1991|p=4}} with this comment:

The concept of a convex set (i.e., a set containing the segment connecting any two of its points) had repeatedly been placed at the center of economic theory before 1964. It appeared in a new light with the introduction of integration theory in the study of economic competition: If one associates with every agent of an economy an arbitrary set in the commodity space and if one averages those individual sets over a collection of insignificant agents, then the resulting set is necessarily convex. [Debreu appends this footnote: "On this direct consequence of a theorem of A. A. Lyapunov, see {{harvtxt|Vind|1964}}."] But explanations of the ... functions of prices ... can be made to rest on the convexity of sets derived by that averaging process. Convexity in the commodity space obtained by aggregation over a collection of insignificant agents is an insight that economic theory owes ... to integration theory. [Italics added]
{{cite news|title=The Mathematization of economic theory|first=Gérard|last=Debreu|authorlink=Gérard Debreu|issue=Presidential address delivered at the 103rd meeting of the American Economic Association, 29 December 1990, Washington, DC|journal=The American Economic Review |volume=81, number 1 |date=March 1991 |pages=1–7 |jstor=2006785}}
7. ^{{cite book|title=Functional analysis and time optimal control|last1=Hermes|first1=Henry |last2=LaSalle|first2=Joseph P.|series=Mathematics in Science and Engineering|volume=56|publisher=Academic Press|location=New York—London|year=1969|pages=viii+136|mr=420366}}
8. ^{{cite news|last=Artstein|first=Zvi|title=Discrete and continuous bang-bang and facial spaces, or: Look for the extreme points|journal=SIAM Review|volume=22|year=1980|number=2|pages=172–185|doi=10.1137/1022026|jstor=2029960 | mr = 564562}}
9. ^{{cite news|last=Tardella|first=Fabio|title=A new proof of the Lyapunov convexity theorem|journal=SIAM Journal on Control and Optimization|volume=28|year=1990|number=2|pages=478–481|doi=10.1137/0328026|mr=1040471}}
10. ^{{cite book|last=Starr|first=Ross M.|authorlink=Ross Starr|chapter=Shapley–Folkman theorem|title=The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics|editor-first=Steven N.|editor-last=Durlauf|editor2-first=Lawrence E., ed.|editor2-last=Blume|publisher=Palgrave Macmillan|year=2008|edition=Second|pages=317–318 (1st ed.)|url=http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_S000107|doi=10.1057/9780230226203.1518|ref=harv}}
11. ^Page 210: {{cite news|last=Mas-Colell|first=Andreu|authorlink=Andreu Mas-Colell|title=A note on the core equivalence theorem: How many blocking coalitions are there?|journal=Journal of Mathematical Economics|volume=5|year=1978|number=3|pages=207–215|doi=10.1016/0304-4068(78)90010-1|mr=514468}}

Books

  • {{Cite book

| last = Cohn
| first = Donald L.
| title = Measure theory
| place = Boston–Basel–Stuttgart
| publisher = Birkhäuser Verlag
| origyear = 1980
| year = 1997
| edition = reprint
| pages = IX+373
| url = https://books.google.com/books?id=vRxV2FwJvoAC&printsec=frontcover&dq=Measure+theory+Cohn&cd=1#v=onepage&q&f=false
| doi =
| zbl = 0436.28001
| isbn = 3-7643-3003-1
| ref = harv
| postscript = {{inconsistent citations}}
}}
  • {{cite book

| last1 = Diestel
| first1 = Joe
| last2 = Uhl
| first2 = Jerry J., Jr.
| title = Vector measures
| series = Mathematical Surveys
| volume = 15
| publisher = American Mathematical Society
| location = Providence, R.I
| year = 1977
| pages = xiii+322
| isbn = 0-8218-1515-6
}}
  • Kluvánek, I., Knowles, G, Vector Measures and Control Systems, North-Holland Mathematics Studies 20, Amsterdam, 1976.
  • {{springerEOM|title=Vector measures|id=Vector_measure|first=D. |last=van Dulst}}
  • {{cite book|last1=Rudin|first1=W|title=Functional analysis|date=1973|publisher=McGraw-Hill|location=New York|page=114}}

See also

  • Bochner integral
{{Use dmy dates|date=September 2011}}{{Functional Analysis}}

3 : Measures (measure theory)|Functional analysis|Control theory

随便看

 

开放百科全书收录14589846条英语、德语、日语等多语种百科知识,基本涵盖了大多数领域的百科知识,是一部内容自由、开放的电子版国际百科全书。

 

Copyright © 2023 OENC.NET All Rights Reserved
京ICP备2021023879号 更新时间:2024/9/22 12:46:05