请输入您要查询的百科知识:

 

词条 Highest averages method
释义

  1. D'Hondt method

  2. Sainte-Laguë method

  3. Imperiali

  4. Huntington-Hill method

  5. Danish method

  6. Quota system

  7. Comparison between the D'Hondt, Sainte-Laguë and Huntington-Hill methods

  8. References

{{refimprove|date=October 2014}}{{Electoral systems}}

The highest averages method or divisor method is the name for a variety of ways to allocate seats proportionally for representative assemblies with party list voting systems. It requires the number of votes for each party to be divided successively by a series of divisors. This produces a table of quotients, or averages, with a row for each divisor and a column for each party. The {{mvar|n}}th seat is allocated to the party whose column contains the {{mvar|n}}th largest entry in this table, up to the total number of seats available.[1]

An alternative to this method is the largest remainder method, which uses a minimum quota which can be calculated in a number of ways.

D'Hondt method

The most widely used is the D'Hondt formula, using the divisors 1, 2, 3, 4, etc.[2] This system tends to give larger parties a slightly larger portion of seats than their portion of the electorate, and thus guarantees that a party with a majority of voters will get at least half of the seats.

Sainte-Laguë method

The Sainte-Laguë method divides the number of votes for each party by the odd numbers (1, 3, 5, 7 etc.) and is sometimes considered "more proportional" than D'Hondt in terms of a comparison between a party's share of the total vote and its share of the seat allocation. This system can favour smaller parties over larger parties and so encourage splits.

Dividing the votes numbers by 0.5, 1.5, 2.5, 3.5 etc. yields the same result.

The Sainte-Laguë method is sometimes modified by increasing the first divisor to e.g. 1.4, to discourage very small parties gaining their first seat "too cheaply".

Imperiali

Another highest average method is called Imperiali (not to be confused with the Imperiali quota which is a Largest remainder method). The divisors are 1, 1.5, 2, 2.5, 3, 3.5 and so on. It is designed to disfavor the smallest parties, akin to a "cutoff", and is used only in Belgian municipal elections. This method (unlike other listed methods) is not strictly proportional, if a perfectly proportional allocation exists, it is not guaranteed to find it.

Huntington-Hill method

In the Huntington-Hill method, the divisors are given by , which makes sense only if every party is guaranteed at least one seat: although this effect can be achieved by disqualifying parties receiving fewer votes than a specified quota, this method is used for allotting seats in the US House of Representatives to the states. (This is not an election, of course.)

Danish method

The Danish method is used in Danish elections to allocate each party's compensatory seats (or levelling seats) at the electoral province level to individual multi-member constituencies. It divides the number of votes received by a party in a multi-member constituency by the growing divisors (1, 4, 7, 10, etc.). Alternatively, dividing the votes numbers by 0.33, 1.33, 2.33, 3.33 etc. yields the same result. This system purposely attempts to allocate seats equally rather than proportionately.[3]

Quota system

In addition to the procedure above, highest averages methods can be conceived of in a different way. For an election, a quota is calculated, usually the total number of votes cast divided by the number of seats to be allocated (the Hare quota). Parties are then allocated seats by determining how many quotas they have won, by dividing their vote totals by the quota. Where a party wins a fraction of a quota, this can be rounded down or rounded to the nearest whole number. Rounding down is equivalent to using the D'Hondt method, while rounding to the nearest whole number is equivalent to the Sainte-Laguë method. However, because of the rounding, this will not necessarily result in the desired number of seats being filled. In that case, the quota may be adjusted up or down until the number of seats after rounding is equal to the desired number.

The tables used in the D'Hondt or Sainte-Laguë methods can then be viewed as calculating the highest quota possible to round off to a given number of seats. For example, the quotient which wins the first seat in a D'Hondt calculation is the highest quota possible to have one party's vote, when rounded down, be greater than 1 quota and thus allocate 1 seat. The quotient for the second round is the highest divisor possible to have a total of 2 seats allocated, and so on.

Comparison between the D'Hondt, Sainte-Laguë and Huntington-Hill methods

D'Hondt, Sainte-Laguë and Huntington-Hill allow different strategies by parties looking to maximize their seat allocation. D'Hondt and Huntington-Hill can favor the merging of parties, while Sainte-Laguë can favor splitting parties (modified Saint-Laguë reduces the splitting advantage).

Examples

In these examples, under D'Hondt and Huntington-Hill the Yellows and Greens combined would gain an additional seat if they merged, while under Sainte-Laguë the Yellows would gain if they split into six lists with about 7,833 votes each.

The Huntington-Hill method threshold is 10000.

D'Hondt methodSainte-Laguë method (unmodified)Sainte-Laguë method (modified)Huntington-Hill method
party Yellow White Red Green Blue Pink Yellow White Red Green Blue Pink Yellow White Red Green Blue Pink Yellow White Red Green Blue Pink
votes 47,000 16,000 15,900 12,000 6,000 3,100 47,000 16,000 15,900 12,000 6,000 3,100 47,000 16,000 15,900 12,000 6,000 3,10047,00016,00015,90012,000 6,000 3,100
mandatequotient
147,00016,00015,90012,000 6,000 3,10047,00016,00015,90012,0006,000 3,10033,57111,42911,3578,571 4,286 2,21433,23411,31411,2438,485Disqualified
223,5008,0007,950 6,000 3,000 1,55015,6675,3335,300 4,000 2,000 1,03315,6675,3335,300 4,000 2,000 1,03319,1876,531 6,491 4,898
315,667 5,333 5,300 4,000 2,000 1,0339,400 3,200 3,180 2,400 1,200 6209,400 3,200 3,180 2,400 1,200 62013,567 4,618 4,589 3,464
411,750 4,000 3,975 3,000 1,500 7756,714 2,857 2,271 1,714 875 4436,714 2,857 2,271 1,714 875 44310,509 3,577 3,555 2,683
59,400 3,200 3,180 2,400 1,200 620 5,222 1,778 1,767 1,333 667 3335,222 1,778 1,767 1,333 667 3338,580 2,921 2,902 2,190
6 7,833 2,667 2,650 2,000 1,000 517 4,273 1,454 1,445 1,091 545 282 4,273 1,454 1,445 1,091 545 2827,252 2,468 2,453 1,851
seatseat allocation
1 47,000 47,000 33,571 33,234 Disqualified
2 23,500 16,000 15,667 21,019
3 16,000 15,900 11,429 14,863
4 15,900 15,667 11,357 11,399
5 15,667 12,000 9,400 11,314
6 12,000 9,400 8,571 11243
7 11,750 6,714 6,714 9217
8 9,400 6,000 5,333 8485
9 8,000 5,333 5,300 7727
10 7,950 5,300 5,222 7155

References

1. ^{{cite book |last=Norris |first=Pippa |date=2004 |title=Electoral Engineering: Voting Rules and Political Behavior |publisher=Cambridge University Press |page=51 |isbn=0-521-82977-1}}
2. ^{{cite journal |last=Gallagher |first=Michael |date=1991 |title=Proportionality, disproportionality and electoral systems |url=http://www.tcd.ie/Political_Science/staff/michael_gallagher/ElectoralStudies1991.pdf |format=pdf |journal=Electoral Studies |publisher= |volume=10 |issue=1 |doi=10.1016/0261-3794(91)90004-C |access-date=30 January 2016 |deadurl=yes |archiveurl=https://web.archive.org/web/20160304030108/https://www.tcd.ie/Political_Science/staff/michael_gallagher/ElectoralStudies1991.pdf |archivedate=4 March 2016 |df= }}
3. ^{{cite web|url= http://www.thedanishparliament.dk/Democracy/Elections_and_referendums/~/media/PDF/publikationer/English/The%20Parliamentary%20System%20of%20Denmark_2011.ashx |title=The Parliamentary Electoral System in Denmark }}
{{voting systems}}

1 : Party-list proportional representation

随便看

 

开放百科全书收录14589846条英语、德语、日语等多语种百科知识,基本涵盖了大多数领域的百科知识,是一部内容自由、开放的电子版国际百科全书。

 

Copyright © 2023 OENC.NET All Rights Reserved
京ICP备2021023879号 更新时间:2024/9/21 15:21:17